75
Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield Curve and Macroeconomic Variables using German Data Diplomarbeit bei Prof. Dr. Svetlozar T. Rachev Institut f¨ ur Statistik und ¨ Okonometrie Universit¨ at Karlsruhe (TH) vorgelegt von Thomas Bernhard Reckers Betreuer: Dipl.-Wi.-Ing. Markus H¨ ochst¨ otter 20. April 2006

Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    9

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Empirical Analysis of the Relationship

between the Yield Curve and

Macroeconomic Variables using German

Data

Diplomarbeit

bei Prof. Dr. Svetlozar T. Rachev

Institut fur Statistik und Okonometrie

Universitat Karlsruhe (TH)

vorgelegt von Thomas Bernhard Reckers

Betreuer: Dipl.-Wi.-Ing. Markus Hochstotter

20. April 2006

Page 2: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Ehrenwortliche Erklarung

Ich versichere hiermit wahrheitsgemaß, die Arbeit selbstandig angefertigt, alle benutzten

Hilfsmittel vollstandig und genau angegeben und alles kenntlich gemacht zu haben, was

aus Arbeiten anderer unverandert oder mit Abanderung entnommen wurde.

Karlsruhe, den 20. April 2006

(Thomas Reckers)

I

Page 3: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Contents

1 Introduction 5

2 Theories about the term structure of interest rates 6

2.1 Traditional economic theories of the term Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.1.1 expectations Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.1.2 Liquidity preference theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.1.3 Market segmentation theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.1.4 Preferred habitat theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.2 Quantitative term structure models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

2.2.1 Short-rate equilibrium models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

2.2.1.1 The Vasicek Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

2.2.1.2 The Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

2.2.2 No-arbitrage models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

2.2.2.1 The Ho and Lee model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10

2.2.2.2 The Hull and White model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

3 Literature review 12

3.1 Inflation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

3.2 GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

3.3 Exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

3.4 Budget deficit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

3.5 Oil price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20

3.6 External interest rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22

4 Data 24

4.1 Interest rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24

4.2 Consumer price index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

4.3 GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

4.4 Ifo business climate index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

4.5 Unemployment rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

4.6 Exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30

4.7 Budget deficit . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

4.8 Oil price . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

4.9 External interest rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

1

Page 4: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

5 Methodology 35

5.1 Stationarity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

5.2 Unit root test . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

5.3 Multicollinearity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

5.4 Granger causality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

6 Empirical analysis 42

6.1 Autoregressive Moving Average Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

6.2 The Box-Jenkins Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

6.3 OLS estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

6.4 VARMA modelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

6.5 Forecasting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

6.6 Time frame estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

6.7 (G)ARCH modelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

6.7.1 ARCH LM Test . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62

6.7.2 (G)ARCH model estimation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63

7 Conclusions 66

Bibliography 67

A Schwarz criterion 71

B Akaike criterion 71

C Adjusted R2 71

D Log-likelihood function 71

E Skewness 71

F Kurtosis 72

G Jarque-Bera (JB) test of normality 72

H Ito process 72

2

Page 5: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Glossary

adf Augmented Dickey-Full test

cpi Consumer price index in %

dcpi 1st difference of the consumer price index in %

dfiscal 1st difference of the new indebtness of the fiscal deficit

dfx 1st difference of the nominal DEM/EUR US$ exchange rate

dgdp 1st difference of the quarterly gross domestic product in %

difo 1st difference of the Ifo business climate index

djapanlong 1st difference of the Japanese government bond yields

djapanshort 1st difference of the Japanese call money rates

djapanslope 1st difference of japanslope

dmths3 1st difference of the 3-months money market rate reported by Frankfurt

doil 1st difference oil price per barrel in Euro

drealfx 1st difference of the real effective exchange rate for DEM/EUR

dslope1y10y 1st difference of the 10-years 1-year slope

dslope1y10y 1st difference of the 10-years 3-months slope

due 1st difference of the quarterly change in % of the unemployment rate

duslong 1st difference of the 10-years yield for US government bonds

dusshort 1st difference of the treasury bill rates

dusslope 1st difference of usslope

dyr1 1st difference of the 1-year yield on listed German Federal securities

dyrs10 1st difference of the 10-years yield on listed German Federal securities

dyrs5 1st difference of the 5-years yield on listed German Federal securities

e.g. for example

fiscal New indebtness of the fiscal deficit

fx Nominal DEM/EUR US$ exchange rate

3

Page 6: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

gdp Quarterly gross domestic product in %

i.e. id est, that means

ifo Ifo business climate index

japanlong Japanese government bond yields

japanshort Japanese call money rates

japanslope Difference of japanlong and japanshort

LB Ljung-Box

LM Lagrange Multiplier

LR Likelihood ratio

mths3 3-months money market rate reported by Frankfurt

oil Oil price per barrel in Euro

realfx Real effective exchange rate for DEM/EUR

SIC Schwarz information criterion

slope1y10y 10-years 1-year slope

slope1y10y 10-years 3-months slope

ue Quarterly change in % of the unemployment rate

uslong 10-years yield for US government bonds

usshort Treasury bill rates

usslope Difference of uslong and usshort

V ARMA Vector autoregressive moving-average

yr1 1-year yield on listed German Federal securities

yrs10 10-years yield on listed German Federal securities

yrs5 5-years yield on listed German Federal securities

4

Page 7: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

1 Introduction

Theoretical and empirical models for the analysis of interest rates represent one of

the most discussed areas in economic research. The level of interest rates plays an

important role in an economy because it strongly influences the extent of investments.

This thesis attempts to conduct an empirical analysis for the German term structure

of interest rates. The term structure of interest plots the relationship between the

interest rate and the maturity of debt and is influenced by several latent and observable

parameters. In this analysis, the focus is on interpreting the impact of macroeconomic

variables on the yield curve but in the empirical section, univariate models are also

estimated and compared with multivariate models.

In the second chapter, a brief overview about traditional and quantitative term structure

models is given. A review of the literature, which deals with the relationship of interest

rates and macroeconomic variable, follows. The data that will be used for the latter

analysis is introduced in the fourth chapter and the subsequent chapter presents basic

econometric tests with these time series. The main part of this thesis is represented

by the empirical analysis. Different uni- and multivariate models are estimated. Based

on these estimation, forecasting and (G)ARCH models are also assessed. Finally, a

summary of the result concludes the paper.

5

Page 8: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

2 Theories about the term structure of interest rates

This chapter introduces traditional and quantitative theories about the term structure

of interest rates. Traditional concepts attempt to explain the yield curve and its shape in

an intuitive way, whereas quantitative theories are precise mathematical models (Cairns,

2004).

2.1 Traditional economic theories of the term Structure

The following term structure theories are all based on traditional economic theory. Each

of these theories emphasises in a different direction. Although these models might be

slightly out of date, they provide some useful hints about how the term structure evolves.

2.1.1 expectations Theory

Among the traditional models, the expectations theory is the oldest approach (Deppner,

1992).Under the assumption that investors view all assets as perfect substitutes, re-

gardless of their maturities, Fisher (1932) basically argues that long-term interest rates

reflect the expectations about future short-term rates.

Let i be the interest rate of a bond. For an n-period bond, the expectations theory

states that the yield of this bond is an average of the expected short-term yields over

the maturity of the bond (Hubbard, 2002):

in,t =i1,t + ie1,t+1 + ... + ie1,t+n−1

n(1)

In line with the expectations theory, the slope of the yield curve reflects what the expecta-

tion of the market about future interest rates are. A downward-sloping (upward-sloping)

curve means that investors presume that future short-term rates will fall (rise) and in

a flat-curve environment, market participants predict short-term will move sideways in

the next periods.

However, this would imply that short-term rates are mostly expected to rise (since the

yield is usually upward-sloping) which is inconsistent with the actual empirical observa-

tions.

6

Page 9: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

2.1.2 Liquidity preference theory

Investors tend to prefer short-term securities, according to the liquidity preference theory,

because long-term assets are likely to be more volatile and hence have a higher price risk

than short-term paper. However, the majority of borrowers favours issuing long-term

bonds because they can hedge their future cash flows for a longer period of time. This

controversial preference for maturities leads to a constitutional weakness on the long

end of the yield curve. In order to raise the desirability of long-term bonds, the issuers

will offer a risk-premium to the creditor and aims to convince the investors who are

indifferent between short- and long-term assets (Hicks, 1950).

2.1.3 Market segmentation theory

The market segmentation theory behaves in an opposite way to the expectations theory.

It assumes that the expectation about future interest rates are uncertain and the par-

ticipants of the capital market are acting risk-averse which means that every individual

will invest in maturities which he prefers (Culbertson, 1957).

Consequently, debtors and creditors will only buy and sell asset with certain maturi-

ties so that the capital market is broken down into delimited and non-substitutable

sub-markets. Between these sub-markets, there is no interaction due to the supposed

risk-aversion and the equilibrium interest rates in every segment is a result of the exist-

ing demand and supply of fixed income assets.

Although it is true that certain investor groups will prefer different maturities (e.g. a

pension fund will most probably prefer long-term assets whereas a bank might prefer

to invest in the short end), in the real world short and long maturities are competing

against each other.

Hence, the market segmentation theory is not a very reasonable description for the term

structure of interest rates.

2.1.4 Preferred habitat theory

Finally, the preferred habitat theory attempts to merge the previously mentioned mod-

els. Investors have a view that different maturities can be substitutes but not perfect

substitutes and they tend to prefer certain maturities but they can be induced to buy

other securities (Modigliani and Sutch, 1966). Hence, they will only switch the maturity

if they get offered a term premium which compensates them for buying a less-preferred

7

Page 10: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

maturity. Under this model, the spread between short and long rates will mainly depend

on the expected change of the long rate but it may also be influenced by the demand and

supply of securities of different maturities, risk aversion, transaction costs and arbitrage

opportunities. The yield for an n-period bond using the preferred habitat theory equals

the average of expected future one-period yields plus the hn,t (habitat) term premium.

in,t =i1,t + ie1,t+1 + ... + ie1,t+n−1

n+ hn,t (2)

The term premium is the crucial difference between the preferred habitat and the previ-

ous theories. While it is always zero under the expectations theory and always positive

under the liquidity preference theory, the preferred habitat theory assumes that the pre-

mium can take on positive as well as negative values. It is obvious that the shape of

the yield curve depends on the expectations about future short-term yields and the size

of the term premium. Since investors typically prefer shorter instead of longer maturi-

ties, hn,t increases with higher maturities. Thus, the preferred habitat theory perfectly

explains why the term structure is mostly upward-sloping even if short-term rates are

not expected to rise soon. A flat (downward-sloping) curve suggests that the market

expects a slight (more significant) fall of short rates.

The preferred habitat theory is therefore the most logical way of explaining the usual

upward-sloping curve and the movement together of short- and long-term rates.

2.2 Quantitative term structure models

There are two main classes of interest rate models: Equilibrium (short-rate) and no-

arbitrage models. Equilibrium models have the disadvantage that their calculated bond

price does not exactly match the observed market price. No-arbitrage models use today’s

term structure as an input and hence, they are consistent with the current yield curve.

Generally, these models are widely used for the pricing of interest rates derivatives (Hull,

1999).

2.2.1 Short-rate equilibrium models

Originally, interest rate models were based on the assumption of specific one-dimensional

dynamics for the instantaneous spot rate process r (Brigo and Mercurio, 2001). Short-

8

Page 11: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

rate equilibrium models follow an Ito process of the form

dr = m(r)dt + s(r)dz

The instantaneous drift, m, and instantaneous standard deviation, s, are assumed to be

functions of r but are independent of time. In this model, all rates move in the same

direction but not necessarily by the same amount. It does not imply that the term

structure always has the same shape (Hull, 1999).

According to Cairns (2004), three basic characteristics are desirable for short-rate mod-

els.

• Interest rates should be positive.

• r(t) should be autoregressive so that it will reach some long-term target and will

not drift to plus or minus infinity or to zero.

• If possible, the model should include a simple formula for bond and derivative

pricing.

The main disadvantage of short-rate models is their endogeneity and the small number

of parameters makes it difficult to properly reproduce some typical shapes of the yield

curve (Brigo and Mercurio, 2001).

2.2.1.1 The Vasicek Model

The model of Vasicek (1977) is probably the best known model.

The risk neutral process for r in the Vasicek Model is

dr = a(b− r)dt + σdz (3)

where a, b and σ are constants. The key feature of the model is its mean-reverting

structure. The stochastic term σdz is normally distributed. In the model:

• b represents the risk-neutral long-term mean risk-free rate

• a represents the rate at which r reverts back to this long-term mean

• σ represents the local volatility of short-term interest rates

The shape produced by the this model can be upward sloping, downward sloping, or

slightly ”humped”(Hull, 1999; Cairns, 2004).

9

Page 12: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

2.2.1.2 The Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model

The main disadvantage of the Vasicek model is that the risk-free rate of interest can

become negative. Even if the probabilities of r(t) becoming negative are small (either

because the timescale is short or because the volatility of r(t) is small), there are many

circumstances and parameter sets where the probability of negative rates can be signif-

icant.

Thus, the model proposed by Cox, Ingersoll and Ross (Cox et al., 1985) keeps rates of

interest positive.

dr = a(b− r)dt + σ√

rdz (4)

The mean-reverting drift is the same as in Vasicek’s model, but the standard deviation is

proportional to√

r, i.e. as the short-term interest rate increases , its standard deviation

increases(Hull, 1999; Cairns, 2004).

2.2.2 No-arbitrage models

No-arbitrage models attempt to solve the described problems which occur when short-

rate models are used. Whereas equilibrium models deliver today’s term structure as an

output, no-arbitrage models treat it as an input. Furthermore, their drift usually de-

pends on time which means that the average path taken by the short rate is influenced

through the initial zero-curve (Hull, 1999).

Cairns (2004) divides no-arbitrage models into two classes. Multifactor, time-

homogeneous models are calibrated to historical data and a close fit between theoretical

and observed prices is achieved by regular calibration of stochastic variables. Secondly,

time-inhomogeneneous, no-arbitrage models use observed prices as a direct input and

therefore the theoretical price exactly matches the observed price. These models are

preferred by market practitioners, because they make sure that the prices of derivatives

from different market makers match and there are no arbitrage opportunities.

2.2.2.1 The Ho and Lee model

Ho and Lee (1986) presented their model in the form of a binomial tree of bond prices

with two parameters: the short-rate standard deviation and the market price of risk of

the short rates. The continuous time limit of the model is:

dr = θdt + σdz (5)

10

Page 13: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

where σ, the instantaneous standard deviation of the short rate, is constant and θ(t) is

function of time to ensure that the model fits the initial term structure (for the analytical

calculation of θ(t) see equation (6))

θ(t) = Ft(0, t) + σ2t (6)

Here, F(0,t) is the instantaneous forward rate for a maturity t as seen at time zero

and the subscript t denotes a partial derivative with respect to t. As θ(t) approximately

equals Ft(0, t), the average direction of the short rate in the future will be moving roughly

equal to the slope of the instantaneous forward curve.

This model exactly fits to the current term structure of interest rates, but it is very

inflexible when it comes to choosing the volatility structure (Hull, 1999; Cairns, 2004).

2.2.2.2 The Hull and White model An extension of the Vasicek model is the frame-

work designed by Hull and White (1990).

dr = a

(θ(t)

a− r

)dt + σdz (7)

where a and σ are constants and. The model can be characterised as the Vasicek model

with a time-dependent variable. At time t the short rate reverts to θ(t)a

at rate a. The

θ(t) function can be derived analytically:

θ(t) = Ft(0, 1) + aF (0, t) +σ2

2a(1− e−2at) (8)

The last of the three terms is usually very small that is why, on average, r approximately

follows the slope of the initial instantaneous forward rate curve. One advantage over the

Ho and Lee model is that this model can represent a wider range of volatility structures.

11

Page 14: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

3 Literature review

The yield curve is a very useful indicator for the transmission of macroeconomic policy

(Turnovsky, 1989). On the one hand, the short end of the curve is determined by

monetary policy markers and depends essentially on the current level of inflation, the

inflation target of a central bank and the level of output activity. However, the long

end of the curve can not directly be influenced by the central bank and therefore is also

driven by other factors such as the exchange rate, the fiscal deficit, the expectations

about future short-term interest rates and external long-term interest rates (see Butter

and Jansen, 2004; Dua et al., 2004). Consequently, there should exist a relationship

between macroeconomic variables and the term structure of interest rates. The term

structure can be used to forecast GDP growth and future inflation. Movements in

macroeconomic fundamentals will have an impact on the shape of the curve and the

level of interest rates. Although, economic theory would suggest that the impact of the

macroeconomy on yields is stronger than vice versa.

For that reason, a model which aims to describe the finance-macro relationship has to

investigate the impact of the financial market on the macroeconomy and the opposite

effect.

3.1 Inflation

The empirical and theoretical relationships between inflation and interest rates are one

of the most discussed subjects in the economic and econometric field.

In his seminal work, Irving Fisher (1932) stated that the nominal rate of interest is the

equilibrium real return plus the fully anticipated rate of price changes in a market which

is well functioning (Fama, 1975). 1 According to Fisher’s theory, the nominal rate has

a one-to-one relationship with the expected inflation since the real rate is independent

of price changes. Therefore, the term structure could be a predictor for future inflation.

However, the outcome of empirical studies is very diverse and the theory is only

validated by some studies.

Inflation targeting is one important element of monetary policy. The European Central

1 The Fisher equation leads to the following conclusion:

1 + i = (1 + r)(1 + π)

π is the anticipated inflation rate, r is the real rate of interest and i is the nominal rate of interest.

12

Page 15: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Bank (ECB) aims to keep the CPI of the Euro Area of below, but close to, 2% and the

Bundesbank was also widely known for its monetary policy on inflation targeting. A

strong increase in the long-term interest rates will be interpreted as a rise in inflation

expectation. A central bank who has an implicit inflation target will consequently raise

short-term interest rates in order to lower inflation expectations of the market and to

indirectly influence the long end of the yield curve (Schich, 1999).

In the next section, some of the empirical papers which deal with the relationship

between the yield curve, current and expected inflation rates will be presented. Firstly,

there is a larger amount of research which uses the term structure to forecast future

inflation.

As already mentioned, Fisher’s ”The theory of interest”which attempts to link current

nominal interest rate and expected inflation (1932) was the starting point for an

enormous amount of economic research. In his book, Fisher uses annual data from

the US and the UK for the period between 1820 to 1924 to verify his hypothesis. The

empirical analysis proves that there is a correlation of 0.8 and higher between long-term

interest rates and price inflation when the inflation is lagged over 20 or more years.

The majority of studies about the US economy dealing with the Fisher effect suggest

that there is indeed a positive relationship between interest rates and inflation but they

do not confirm Fisher’s claim of a one-to-one relationship (Cooray, 2002). In an earlier

study by Yohe and Karnosky (1969), prices level changes are confirmed to be the main

determinant of changes in the nominal interest rates. Their results suggest that the

time horizon of forming inflation expectation increases as the term to maturity of the

fixed-income security increases.

Mishkin (1992), analysing monthly US Data from January 1953 to December 1990,

argues that the level of inflation and interest rates may be the result of a stochastic

trend and the apparent short-term forecasting relationship between both is spurious.

However, cointegration test for a common trend of both series suggest that a long-run

Fisher effect might exist. Looking at different subperiods, Fisher observes that the

long-run Fisher effect is particularly strong when both series seem to exhibit a stochastic

trend (January 1953 to October 1979). For periods when it seems as inflation does not

have a trend, the Fisher effect is not measurable (November 1979 to December 1990).

There are a few pieces of research which attempt to investigate whether the Fisher

effect is valid for German data. In a multicountry study, Mishkin (1984) only finds very

small evidence for the existence of the effect in Germany. Unlike the previous result,

Yuhn (1996), using quarterly data from 1973:II to 1993:II for short- and long-term

13

Page 16: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

nominal interest rates and inflation rates for five industrialised countries (US, UK,

Japan, Germany and Canada), points out that German inflation rate and interest rate

have the strongest relationship among the investigated countries. His empirical study

uses Johansen’s cointegration tests in order to verify the link.

With the implementation of a threshold cointegration model which takes into account

that inflation and interest rates in developed countries fluctuate in a narrow band,

Weidmann (1997) shows that there is indeed a one-to-one relationship between the two

variables.

Although the Bundesbank did not introduce their inflation target of 2% per year before

1986, it interpreted its task to safeguard the internal value of the DM. The ECB, which

conduct the monetary policy for Germany, has adopted this inflation target. Higher

inflation will thus increase the probability of a rise in nominal short-term rates by the

central bank. Since actual and expected inflation do not change significantly in the

short-run, one should actually expect how the real interest rate and inflation will evolve

due to the known policy of the inflation targeting bank (Leidermann and Svensson,

1995).

Bernanke and Mihov (1997) use a (VAR)-based approach in order to analyse how the

Bundesbank has responded to changes in money growth and which impacts the German

central bank’s policy had on prices and other key variables. As already mentioned, the

Bundesbank did not have an official inflation target until 1986, it still had an implicit

target (the so-called ”‘unavoidable inflation”’). Comparing the deviation between the

actual and the targeted money growth as well as the deviation of the actual inflation

and the ”‘unavoidable inflation”’ in the period from 1975 to 1995, the authors notice

that it seems as if the money growth target is subservient because the volatility of the

inflation targets is lower and it declines steadily (except in the oil-shock-year, 1980).

Taking also other computations of the paper into account, the Bundesbank turns out

to be rather an inflation targeter than a money targeter.

3.2 GDP

Current inflation and the expectations about the future level of inflation can explain

much of the nominal interest rate but the shape of the term structure can also explain

future real economic activity.

Forecasting real economic growth is fundamental for policymakers and businesses. How-

14

Page 17: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

ever, macroeconomic models are often very complex and inaccurate. Using financial

data as an input to predict the real GDP growth makes sense because the figures are

immediately available and are precise.

The term spread which is the difference between short-term and long-term interest rates

has been a useful predictor for real economic growth. While an upward sloping suggests

that the economy will expand, a negative yield spread is associated with future economic

tightening.

There are two explanations for this empirical relationship which are discussed among

researchers.

The first reason for the correlation may be that the term spread reflects the stance of

monetary policy. If the policymakers raise short-term interest rates, long-term rates are

usually not increasing one-to-one with them but slightly less. Hence, the spread tightens

and even might become negative. Higher interest rates slow down overall spending and

economic growth will stagnate. Therefore, a small or negative slope of the yield curve

will be an indication for slower growing economy in the future.

Secondly, the yield spread might reflect the market expectations about future economic

growth. If businesses and market participants anticipate that the real income will in-

crease in the future. The increase in expected future real income will cause a rise in

borrowing by businesses because they expect profitable investment opportunities. As

they typically issue long-term debt, the supply for these bonds will increase and prices

will go down. The yield of the longer paper will increase relative to the short-term rates

and the curve will consequently become steeper (Bonser-Neal and Morley, 1997).

In an analytical rational expectations models, Estrella (2005) attempts to explain the

rationale for the significance of the yield slope. According to this model, monetary policy

is the main reason for the forecasting power of the term structure. Essentially, monetary

policy reacts if there are deviations from targeted inflation or potential output growth.

If the monetary policymakers systematically aim to achieve these goals, the predictive

power of the term structure is more directly dependant on macroeconomic variables.

The quality of the prediction is therefore the result of the form of the monetary policy

reaction function.

In a multicountry empirical analysis for 11 industrial countries (1972:1 - 1996:4), Bonser-

Neal and Morley (1997) aim to measure the forecasting power of the term spread. In the

in-sample model, the explanatory power of Germany’s term spread (on the 10-years gov-

ernment bond and the 3-month interbank rate) is among the highest, only exceeded by

Canada and the United States. On average, the slope of curve accounts for about 30% of

15

Page 18: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

the future real GDP growth in Germany, if one looks at a 1- to 3-years forecast horizon.

Regardless of the investigated country, the coefficient confirms the positive relationship

between the term spread and real GDP growth. In order to testify that the yield spread

is the best predictor for future growth, the authors compare the out-of-sample forecast

power of the yield spread model with two alternative forecasting models, a model which

uses the lagged real GDP growth and the second model combines both variables in one

equation. The root mean squared error (RMSE) statistic which measure the accuracy

of the different forecasts suggests that the pure yield spread model outperforms the al-

ternative models.

In one of the first multicountry studies, Harvey (1991) analyses quarterly data from the

G-7 countries (period 1970:1 - 1989:4). He uses the term spread in quarter t between a

bond that has five quarters to maturity and a bond that has one quarter to maturity

to make a forecast for the GNP growth from quarter t+1 to quarter t+5. The forecast

for Germany has an adjusted R2 of almost 30% and is only exceeded by the US and

Canada.

Plosser and Rouwenhorst (1994) conduct an empirical study for the US, Germany,

France, Canada and the UK. When they investigate quarterly data, their main find-

ing is that the term spread is a better forecaster of real output and consumption than

of nominal output or consumption growth in Germany (period 1960:1 - 1991:3). In a

second exercise, they regress the annualised growth rate of industrial production on the

short-term rate (1 year) or on both the short term rate and the term spread between

year k and year 1 where k is the forecast horizon. Interestingly, the coefficient of the

term spread for Germany and the US does not change significantly if the short-term rate

is added to the equation. Consequently, the predictive power of the spread is not caused

by the fact that the yield spread is correlated with the level of the short-term rate which

might point out that the information content of the curve slope is not due to the level

of the short-term rate but rather reflects market expectations about future growth.

Although it seems as the empirical relationship between the slope and growth variable

is evident, there are also studies which compute a much lesser correlation coefficients.

Bange (1996) evaluates the influence of the yield spread on future growth for Japan,

Germany and the US. Among the three countries, Germany exhibits the smallest cor-

relation if the dependent variable is the quarterly growth rate of industrial production

while the 1-period lagged variable of the dependent variable is the first explanatory

variable and the second explanatory variable is the spread (between the rate on three

month loans and the yield of a long-term government bond with a maximum maturity

16

Page 19: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

of four years). Even though the period chosen by Bange (1973:1 - 1988:1) is very similar

to the Harvey’s selection and the regression equation are comparable, Bange computes

a R2 which is 20% lower for Germany and 15% higher for Japan compared to Harvey’s

results. This might refer to the fact that the achieved correlation depends very much on

the formulation of the regression equation and the chosen data period.

3.3 Exchange rate

Germany, as the so-called export world champion who exports the largest amount of

goods in US$, relies heavily on trade relationship with foreign countries. Although the

largest trading partner are mainly in Europe, many exports go into the United States,

Asia and the Middle East. Thus, exchange rates especially affect the performance of

domestic businesses who generate a large revenue in US$ or in currencies which are

correlated/pegged with the US$. A depreciating US$ vs. the local currency harms

domestic corporations because their spending are usually in the local currency and hence,

prices are fixed in this currency. If the foreign currency decreases in value, domestic

companies have to offer their products at a higher price and the export demand lessens.

In the opposite case (an appreciation of the domestic currency), export demand increases.

In other words, the value of a currency has an impact on the economic growth, if a

country has large trading activities. So far, this example has not taken price changes

into consideration that means this model, which reflects the value of one currency in

terms of another, looks at the movements of the nominal exchange rate (Hubbard, 2002).

The real exchange rate takes also the purchasing power of the currency into account. It

can be expressed by the following equation where EXr is the real exchange rate, EX the

nominal exchange rate, P the domestic price index and Pf the foreign price index.

EXr =EX ∗ P

Pf

(9)

The percentage change of the real exchange rate is computed as follows:

∆EXr

EXr

=∆EX

EX+

∆P

P− ∆Pf

Pf

(10)

An international term structure model is used by Inci and Lu (2004) to explain exchange

rates. As we have already discussed in the previous sections, the term structure includes

a significant amount of information about the market’s expectation of future inflation

17

Page 20: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

and economic growth. According to the authors, the uncovered interest rate parity

relationship is too simplistic in order to describe the effects between short- and long-

term interest rates. Their model which combines the yield for bonds of eight different

maturities for up to 5 years denominated in US$ /DEM and exchange rate data for

the US$/DEM pair is used to conduct an in-sample forecast (from January 1974 to

December 1998). Their best-performing contemporaneous model has a mean of 0.5053

$/DEM compared to the actual value of 0.5055 $/DEM and a volatility of 0.1072%

compared to the actual volatility of 0.1095% and one can therefore conclude that the

empirical model very well explains currency movements.

Byeon and Ogaki (1999) examine the empirical link between exchange rates and the

yield curve. They regress the log of real exchange rates for a number of developed

countries (April 1973 - April 1995) on the short-term real interest rate differential and

the long-term real interest rate differential. If the equation includes both differentials,

the coefficient for the long-term interest rate differential is negative for all the examined

exchange rates. However, the coefficient of the short-term real interest rate differential is

typically positive for the majority of the investigated exchange rates. The model suggest

that the relationship between short- and long-term interest rates as well as exchanger

rates is of a very complex nature. Another empirical result of the study is that the effect

of monetary policy actions on the exchange rate mainly depends on how the long-term

rate reacts to this change. If the central bank raises interest rates and the long end

shifts upwards as well, the domestic currency appreciates. In case that the long-term

rate moves sideways, the higher short-term rate will cause the domestic currency to

depreciate. An interesting exercise is conducted by Clostermann and Schnatz (2000)

who are using a ”synthetic”euro exchange rate to explore the determinants of the real

effective euro exchange rate. Using quarterly data from 1975:1 to 1998:4, they find out

that real interest rate differential is significant when they estimate a single equation

error correction model (SEECM). According to their regression equation, a rise of 1% in

the short-term in the real interest rate differential results in a 1.3% increase in the real

effective exchange rate.

3.4 Budget deficit

The impact of fiscal policy on interest rates is a widely debated issue. A number of

theoretical approaches attempt to explain why the fiscal deficit might have an impact

on interest rates (Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis, 1995). According to an often uttered

18

Page 21: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

thesis, an increase of the government deficit might lead to a rise of real interest rates.

Higher interest rates will cause a weaker consumer demand and faltering businesses. A

high level of public debt will also trigger inflationary pressure and hence, the central

bank will raise the short-term rate. As market participants would expect a continuous

tightening of the monetary policy, long-term rates will go upwards in line with the short

end of the curve.

The loanable fund model assumes the existence of a market where consumer demand

(household’s savings S) and demand for funds meet (D fiscal deficit, Z private invest-

ment) meet, hence an increase of the deficit leads to lower investments and higher savings.

Public debt issues could also influence the risk premium which investors are willing to

pay for long-term bonds instead of short-term paper (Decoudre, 2005).

Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis (1995) empirically analyse the relationship between nom-

inal and real long-term interest rates and budget deficits. They concentrate on long-term

rates because these are a key determinant of capital accumulation and play a central

role in the transmission of macroeconomic policies to the economy. In their study, they

investigate annual data from 1970 to 1993 for 10 OECD countries including Germany.

In order to estimate the nominal long-term rates iL, the real short-term rate rs, the

budget to GDP ratio d and the expected inflation rate πe is taken.

iL = α0 + α1rs + α2πe + α3d + u (11)

The employed equation leads to a R2 which is above 80% in every country. The coefficient

for the budget to GDP ratio is significant in all countries with the theoretically predicted

positive sign.

Secondly, they test whether the long-term interest rates might not be only influenced

by the current fiscal deficit but also by the stock of accumulated public debt which

reflects the supply of sovereign bonds in the market. In this model, investors will ask for

an additional risk premium, if the country’s debt relative to income is high. However,

adding this ratio to the equation does not improve the performance of the estimation.

Decoudre (2005) rebuilds Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis’ model with the same data.

He criticises that the fiscal surplus data is not cyclically-adjusted and includes interest

payments on debt. Repeating the estimation with the identical data but the cyclically

adjusted primary balance, Germany’s R2 goes down from 0.84 to 0.55 and the t-statistic

is not significant anymore. Due to the result of the estimation, Decoudre concludes that

Correia-Nunes and Stemitsiotis’ analysis can not be regarded as statistical and robust.

19

Page 22: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

This brief overview shows how debatable it is whether the public deficit influence interest

rates or not but it seems reasonable to include the variable in the subsequent following

model.

3.5 Oil price

At first glance, the likely relationship between the yield curve and the oil price may

not be obvious but there are indications that high energy prices, as a major input to

production, are causing recessions and lower economic growth. Consequently, oil price

shocks which lead to economic depression and excessive inflation would also have an

impact on monetary policy. If one looks closer at the statistical relationship between

political events in the Middle East and recession in the US which were caused by an oil

price shock, the belief of a connection is supported. However, the lag between crisis in

the oil-producing countries and recession in the US is quite stretched. There also seems

to be some empirical evidence for a link between the oil price, productivity and inflation

(Barsky and Kilian, 2004).

It has to be pointed out that the linkages between energy and economic aggregates are

of a complex nature. Firstly, a rise of energy prices can have an effect on the aggregate

production function. Demand may also alter due to an oil price increase. In addition,

an upward shift of energy prices will usually cause a transfer of income from the oil

importing countries to the oil exporting countries and the income decrease will trigger a

lessening of consumer spending which will reduce aggregate demand and output. Lastly,

the energy price increase might also lead to other actions, for instance, monetary policy

could be forced to tighten and would lower real economic activity (Bjørnland, 2000).

Although the majority of the research in this area deals with the US economy, there are

a few studies which undertake multi-country studies. Carrying out multivariate vector

autoregressions, Jimenez-Rodrıguez and Sanchez (2004) explore the effects of oil price

shocks on the real economic activity in the main industrialised OECD countries (period

1972:3 - 2000:4) and estimate linear/non-linear models. The Granger-causality test show

that the different oil prices variables are not statistically significant at a 5% critical level

for most of the countries if the real GDP of period is estimated with lagged values of

real GDP, real effective exchange rate (REER), real oil price, real wage, inflation, short

and long-term interest rates. Furthermore, they observe the response to oil price shocks

in different countries and find out that, in the case of positive movements in oil prices,

there is a similar pattern reaction among the net oil importing countries and the largest

20

Page 23: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

negative short-run effect occurs within a year. As one would expect, the strongest re-

sponse takes place in the US (the accumulated loss GDP growth is 3.2%) , whereas

Germany’s economy only reacts half as strong as the US with 1.6%.

In a recent study of Schmidt and Zimmermann (2005), the effects of oil price shocks

are especially analysed for the German economy. Since 1970, the openness of the Ger-

man economy (an indication is the ratio of the im- and export divided by GDP) has

more than doubled. During the same period, the usage of energy in percent of GDP

has halved. In order to take these developments into account, the year 1986, where

the oil price dropped from 40$ to 20$ due to a production increase, divides the sample

into two subperiods. Comparing the two sample periods, their main finding is that oil

price shocks only contribute a declining and limited extent to business cycle fluctuations

because the importance of the energy use has been decreasing.

The previously presented research dealt with the impact of the oil price on GDP growth

but energy prices also influence inflation. LeBlanc and Chinn (2004) conduct an empir-

ical investigation about the effects of oil price changes on inflation in the G-5 countries.

There are two main reason why it is the common belief that European countries might

respond more to oil price increases: The European countries tend to have stronger labour

unions which are more likely to enforce wage increases due to rising inflation and since

product market competition is not as concentrated as in the US, European producers

will possibly pass along the higher wages to consumers. This wage-price spiral does

usually not occur in the US where workers are more likely to absorb through higher fuel

prices and increases in other energy-related products.

Using a short-run Phillips curve approach, the authors estimate an equation which has

inflation on the left hand side and lags of inflation, unemployment rate, interest rates

and the percentage change in nominal oil prices on the explanatory side of the equation.

Like Schmidt and Zimmermann (2005), they also find out that the one-year inflationary

impact of higher oil price has declined when they estimate the coefficients for the period

from 1980:1 to 1990:4 and extend the sample period by one observation each time up to

2001:4. In the following step, the whole sample is compared to the other G-5 countries.

In Germany, the oil price has only a very small impact. A 10% increase in the oil price

leads only to a maximum inflationary effect of 0.5% depending on the estimation model,

whereas the effect on US inflation is only slightly stronger with 0.8%. The US, the UK

and Japan show generally stronger responses to oil price increases than Germany and

France. As a conclusion, one can say that inflation in the G-5 countries is not very

sensitive to oil prices and that there are no significant differences in the relationship

21

Page 24: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

between the US and other G-5 countries. The previously mentioned effects for Europe

might be offset by the higher energy sensitivity of the US economy.

Having looked at different empirical studies, it seems as if the impact of the oil price

on the GDP growth and inflation has diminished in the past decades, but was more

important in the 70’s.

3.6 External interest rates

In a world, where financial markets are highly integrated and capital can be moved within

seconds, it is sensible to also include external interest rates. In this thesis, the American

and Japanese interest rates will be included because they are the two other major bond

markets. The following equation (see Chinn and Frankel, 2005) shows the theoretical

linkage between the difference in nominal interest rates between two economies on assets

of equal maturity and default risk, when expressed in common currency terms.

(ikt − ik∗t) = [ikt − ik∗t − (ft,t+k − EXt)] + (ft,t+k − EXet+k) + (EXe

t+k − EXt) (12)

The term in square brackets is called covered interest rate differential (ft,t+k is the

forward exchange rate from period t to t + k and EXt is the exchange in period t),

(ft,t+k −EXet+k) is the exchange rate risk premium and (EXe

t+k −EXt) is the expected

appreciation/depreciation of the exchange rate. When both of these terms turn zero,

the interest rate differential equals the expected depreciation.

Chinn and Frankel (2005) analyse how US and European interest rates have influenced

each other in the past decades. For money market rates, they find evidence that the

US real rates have a greater impact on the German real rate than the reverse (period

1973-2004) and this pattern does not change with the inception of the EMU. In terms of

real long-term rates, a vector error correction equation over the identical sample period

is formulated to investigate the causality relations. Up to 1995, US rates did not re-

spond to Europeans rates at all but the opposite was frequently the case. In the second

subperiod from 1996 on, this relationship changes and it is observable that sides react

to the movement of the counterpart.

Engsted and Tanggard (2005) use monthly US and German long-term government bond

yields (from 1975 to 2003) to implement a VAR-based variance decomposition of bond

returns. Their empirical study confirms the results of Chinn and Frankel: US real inter-

est rates have a stronger predictive power for German real rates and excess bond return

than vice-versa.

22

Page 25: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

A vector-autoregressive framework is used by Wang et al. (2004) to examine linkages

between government bond markets (indices) of five industrialized countries (US, Japan,

Germany, UK and Canada) during the period of January 1986 to December 2000. Firstly,

a cointegration test shows no evidence of a long-run relationship during most of the

sample period. However, e.g. Smith (2002) supplies evidence for the existence of coin-

tegration among bond markets for a similar period and countries. We can therefore

conclude that the outcome of these test highly depends on the specification of the data

set. Multivariate Granger causality tests are used to study the short-term dynamics

among the markets. The results at the 10% significance level show a clear dominance of

the US, whereby German rates may be influenced by the US and Japan. However, the

5% significance level does merely indicate an influence of the US on Germany, therefore

it appears that the linkages are generally quite weak. After composing a directed graph

based on likelihood ratio tests, variance decompositions are applied in order to quantify

the economic significance of economic variables. According to the results, 74% of the

movements in the German bond market are caused by domestic factors. The remaining

share is originated by Japan (about 21%) and the US (about 5%)

In an earlier work, Clare and Lekkos (2000) undertake a decomposition of the covari-

ation between long-term bonds. In their sample period (August 1991 - October 1999,

weekly data), on average 70% of the German yield curve slope variation is determined

by German factors. The covariance between the German and US yield slope seems to

be mainly driven by macroeconomic fundamentals rather than by risk premia.

Having examined different research on the correlation of bond markets, one cannot deny

that there are linkages among them. Thus, it is appropriate to estimate models with

external rates as well as models which only consist of domestic variables.

23

Page 26: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

4 Data

This chapter introduces the time series data used. Time series are taken from different

sources (Deutsche Bundesbank, Federal Statistical Office, Ifo and International Financial

Statistics). If not stated otherwise, data from 1992 on is for the whole federal territory

of Germany and earlier data only covers the former West Germany.

The study uses quarterly data because the object of the study is to look at possible long-

run relationships between the yield curve and macroeconomic fundamentals. Certain

data sets are published in a monthly interval, therefore the average of three months is

taken in order to obtain quarterly data. In case that only yearly data is available, the

weighted average is used for the first, second and third quarter, while the fourth quarter

of the year contains the actual annual figure.

As the official time series for the yield data of the Deutsche Bundesbank begins at the

end of 1972 and the collapse of the Bretton-Woods system of fixed exchange rates also

falls in the same period, the analysed period starts in the first quarter of 1973 (including

131 observations until 2005Q3).

4.1 Interest rates

In order to investigate the impact of macroeconomic data on the term structure, one

needs the financial data derived from listed German Federal securities. Figure 1 plots the

monthly average of 3-months (mths3), money market rate reported by Frankfurt (Time

series key: su0107), 1-year (yr1), 5-years (yrs5) and 10-years (yrs10) yield of the term

structure on listed Federal securities (Time series key: wz9808, wz9816 and wz9826).

Figure 2 shows the slope of the yield curve, i.e. the difference between the 10-years

yield and 1-year yield (slope1y10y)as well as the difference between the 10-years and the

3-months yield (slope3m10y). All this data is extracted from the time series database

of the Deutsche Bundesbank. The key descriptional statistics are presented in Table 1.

24

Page 27: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 1: 3-months, 1-year, 5-years and 10-years yield

Figure 2: Slope 10 years - 1 year and Slope 10 years - 3months

25

Page 28: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

slope3m10y slope1y10y mths3 yr1 yrs5 yrs10

Mean 1.140 1.198 5.762 5.705 6.560 6.997Maximum 4.610 3.680 14.370 12.660 11.200 11.210Minimum -4.750 -2.280 2.040 2.050 2.710 3.240Std. Dev. 1.722 1.180 2.855 2.448 1.997 1.743Skewness -0.806 -.0517 0.911 0.581 0.076 -0.015Kurtosis 3.726 2.738 3.084 2.519 2.187 2.391

Table 1: Descriptive statistics of the yield data

mths3 yr1 yrs5

mths3 1 0.936 0.770yr1 0.936 1 0.894yrs5 0.770 0.894 1yrs10 0.675 0.795 0.973

slope3m10y 0.657 0.469 0.190slope1y10y 0.595 0.538 0.228

yrs10 slope3m10y slope1y10y

mths3 0.675 0.657 0.595yr1 0.795 0.469 0.538yrs5 0.973 0.190 0.228yrs10 1 0.107 0.117

slope3m10y 0.107 1 0.846slope1y10y 0.117 0.846 1

Table 2: Adjusted R-squared of the yield variables

4.2 Consumer price index

The consumer price index (cpi) is computed monthly by the Federal Statistical Office of

Germany and was published in November 2005 (see figure 3).

26

Page 29: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 3: CPI

4.3 GDP

Quarterly real GDP growth (price-adjusted to 1995) is also provided by the Federal

Statistical Office (see figure 4).

27

Page 30: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 4: GDP

4.4 Ifo business climate index

As a monthly indicator for the economic situation, the Ifo (Institute for Economic Re-

search) in Munich publishes the business climate indices. As the business climate index

is only available from 1980Q1 on, it will be approximated by the mean of the business

situation and expectations index between 1973Q1 and 1979Q4. From 1991Q1 on, the

index covers the reunified Germany.

28

Page 31: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 5: Ifo business climate index

4.5 Unemployment rate

As a proxy for the current economic situation, the unemployment rate can be useful.

The seasonally-adjusted time series is obtained from the Federal Statistical Office (Time

series code: UACC02).

29

Page 32: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 6: Unemployment rate

4.6 Exchange rate

In order to examine the influence of the German exchange rate, nominal and real ex-

change rates are going into the model (see Chapter 3.3). As the US$ is the lead-

ing world currency, the DEM/EUR US$ exchange rate is used in the data set (Code

DEM:134..RF.ZF... and EUR: 134..RF.ZF...). The real effective exchange rate includes

the price-adjusted exchange rate of other major currencies and the weighted average of

the different real exchange is calculated by using the value of trade with the respective

countries (Code: 134..REUZF..., Start: 1975:1). Both time series (see figure 7 and table

3) are provided by the International Financial Statistics.

30

Page 33: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Nominal exchange rate Real effective exchange rate

Mean 1.031855 92.27707Maximum 1.665 122.21Minimum 0.714 68.45Std. Dev. 0.218682 14.76788Skewness 0.69082 0.069216Kurtosis 2.612219 1.89151

Table 3: Descriptive statistics of exchange rate data

Figure 7: Nominal exchange rate and real effective exchange rate

4.7 Budget deficit

Published by the Federal Statistical Office, the new indebtness covers the increase of

public debt per year including subsovereign debt. As the budget deficit is only available

on a year basis, quarterly data is obtained by dividing the annual movement by four.

31

Page 34: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 8: Budget Deficit

4.8 Oil price

The UK brent crude oil price in Euro is extracted from the ZIS database of the Deutsche

Bundesbank. One can clearly recognise the two major oil crises starting at the end of

1973 and at 1979.

32

Page 35: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 9: Oil price per Barrel in Euro

4.9 External interest rates

Lastly, short and long-term rates from Japan and the US are used to estimate the

German yields. These time series are also taken from the IFS database. For the US,

treasury bill rates (IFS code: 11160C..ZF...) and 10 years government bond yields

(IFS code: 11161...ZF...) are taken. Call money rates (IFS code: 15860B..ZF...) and

government bond yields (IFS code: 15861...ZF...) provide the basis for the Japanese

data.

33

Page 36: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

uslong usshort japanlong japanshort

Mean 7.786 6.137 5.033 4.359Maximum 14.847 15.087 9.533 13.037Minimum 3.620 0.916 0.653 0.001Std. Dev. 2.554 2.992 2.838 3.594Skewness 0.753 0.700 -0.024 0.418Kurtosis 3.145 3.741 1.581 2.443

Table 4: Descriptive statistics of the external interest rates data

Figure 10: Short- and long-term interest rates for Japan and the US

34

Page 37: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

5 Methodology

Having introduced the data series in the previous chapter, the next step is a deeper

analysis of the time series properties. With these results, the subsequent section can

undertake the actual empirical analysis. For all the empirical test and calculations,

EViews 5.1 is used.

5.1 Stationarity

The concept of stationarity is vital in time series analysis because it can strongly

influence its properties. In order to be weakly or covariance stationary, a time series

must satisfy the following conditions (Verbeek, 2004).

E(yt) = µ < ∞

V ar(yt) = σ2 < ∞

cov(yt, yt−k) = E{(yt − µ)(yt − k)} = γk, k = 1, 2, 3, ...

Weak stationarity implies that a process has a constant mean, a constant variance and

a constant autocovariance structure. Strong stationarity would require that the joint

distribution of a time series is invariant under time shift which is almost impossible to

prove empirically (Tsay, 2002).

The use of non-stationary data leads to several problems. Time series with a unit root

might trend over time. Therefore, the regression of two unrelated time series might have

a high R2. This phenomenon is called spurious regression. In addition, the ’t-ratios’ do

not follow a t-distribution if the input variables of the regression are not stationary. An

unexpected ’shock’ might also cause difficulties when dealing with non-stationary series

(Brooks, 2002).

5.2 Unit root test

Most economic time series exhibit strong trends. A random walk with drift is the sum

of an infinite number of random variables which are being generated by the same zero-

mean, constant-variance distribution. If this is given, the variance of yt would obviously

35

Page 38: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

be infinite and the random walk is a non-stationary process (also in case µ equals zero).

yt =∞∑i=0

(µ + εt−i) (13)

yt is said to be integrated of order one, I(1). Taking the first difference produces a

stationary process (Greene, 1997).Generally a non-stationary series is integrated of order

d, I(d), if it becomes stationary after being first differenced d times.

In this master thesis, the augmented Dickey-Fuller (adf) Test is employed which can

accommodate higher-order autoregressive processes in εt.

∆yt = γ∗yt−1 +

p−1∑j=1

φj∆yt−j + εt (14)

where

φj = −p∑

k=j+1

γk

and

γ∗ = (

p∑i=1

γi)− 1

The adf test has the null hypothesis γ∗ = 0 and is rejected if γ∗ < 0. In Equation (14),

the regressions estimates a pure random walk model. By adding µ or βt to the equation,

one can include an intercept or a linear time trend (Enders, 1995).

In table 5, we have computed the adf test statistics for the examined time series. The

second, third and fourth column show the chosen number of lagged difference terms, the

t-statistics and the critical value level to which H0 (Yt has a unit root) can be rejected.

The appropriate lag length is determined by the Schwarz criterion whereby a maximum

of 12 lags is considered. The test were conducted for level and first difference data.

Most of the level data indeed has a unit root. However, the slope and 3-months money

market time series as well as the GDP and the Ifo index data seem to be stationary

according to the adf test. The first difference data is clearly stationary for all data sets

(the high t-Statistic for the budget deficit is due to the artificial generation of quarterly

data out of yearly data).

36

Page 39: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Level DataLag (SIC) t-Statistic Reject H0

yrs10 1 -1.57 noyrs5 1 -1.74 noyr1 1 -2.47 no

mths3 1 -3.74 1%slope3m10y 1 -4.59 1%slope1y10y 1 -3.31 5%

cpi 0 -1.99 nogdp 0 -4.67 1%ifo 1 -4.37 1%ue 2 -1.90 no

fxrate 1 -2.11 norealfx 0 -0.84 nofiscal 9 -2.32 nooil 1 -2.05 no

1st DifferenceLag (SIC) t-Statistic Reject H0

yrs10 0 -8.02 1%yrs5 0 -8.21 1%yr1 0 -8.16 1%

mths3 0 -7.78 1%slope3m10y 0 -8.12 1%slope1y10y 0 -8.33 1%

cpi 0 -10.76 1%gdp 0 -13.60 1%ifo 0 -6.13 1%ue 1 -4.53 1%

fxrate 0 -8.70 1%realfx 0 -9.80 1%fiscal 8 -2.68 10%oil 0 -9.90 1%

Table 5: Adf test statistics

37

Page 40: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

5.3 Multicollinearity

In case of multicollinearity, the explanatory variables are intercorrelated which means

that they have an either exact or approximately exact linear relationship. Since this

phenomenon refers to the condition of the explanatory variables, it is not possible to

test for multicollenearity but only to measure the degree of it. The following rules of

the thumb can help detecting the strength (Gujarati, 1995).

• High R2 but few significant t ratios

• High pair-wise correlation among regressors

• Examination of partial correlations

• Auxiliary regressions

Table 6 shows the pair-wise correlation of all regressors. According to Gujarati, the

correlation coefficient should be in excess of 0.8 in order to have serious problems with

multicollinearity which does not apply in this sample.

38

Page 41: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

dcpi dgdp difo due dfiscal dfxrate drealfx

dcpi 1.000 -0.086 -0.121 -0.137 -0.024 0.050 0.026dgdp -0.086 1.000 0.355 -0.051 0.013 0.012 0.030difo -0.121 0.355 1.000 -0.148 -0.098 0.025 -0.088due -0.137 -0.051 -0.148 1.000 0.037 0.078 -0.109

dfiscal -0.024 0.013 -0.098 0.037 1.000 -0.134 0.220dfxrate 0.050 0.012 0.025 0.078 -0.134 1.000 -0.496drealfx 0.026 0.030 -0.088 -0.109 0.220 -0.496 1.000

doil 0.051 -0.009 0.032 -0.030 -0.013 0.396 -0.283djapanlong 0.069 0.101 0.030 -0.128 -0.071 0.167 -0.098djapanshort 0.148 -0.225 -0.169 -0.154 -0.087 -0.073 0.056djapanslope -0.121 0.317 0.204 0.084 0.047 0.193 -0.124

duslong 0.109 0.037 0.099 -0.044 -0.068 0.208 -0.304dusshort -0.019 0.054 0.134 -0.136 -0.022 0.055 -0.199dusslope 0.122 -0.041 -0.094 0.145 -0.030 0.109 -0.008

doil djapanl. djapansh. djapansl. dusl. dussh. dussl.

dcpi 0.051 0.069 0.148 -0.121 0.109 -0.019 0.122dgdp -0.009 0.101 -0.225 0.317 0.037 0.054 -0.041difo 0.032 0.030 -0.169 0.204 0.099 0.134 -0.094due -0.030 -0.128 -0.154 0.084 -0.044 -0.136 0.145

dfiscal -0.013 -0.071 -0.087 0.047 -0.068 -0.022 -0.030dfxrate 0.396 0.167 -0.073 0.193 0.208 0.055 0.109drealfx -0.283 -0.098 0.056 -0.124 -0.304 -0.199 -0.008

doil 1.000 0.416 0.219 0.043 0.299 0.241 -0.062djapanlong 0.416 1.000 0.446 0.191 0.377 0.216 0.040djapanshort 0.219 0.446 1.000 -0.793 -0.029 -0.086 0.091djapanslope 0.043 0.191 -0.793 1.000 0.289 0.241 -0.070

duslong 0.299 0.377 -0.029 0.289 1.000 0.670 -0.025dusshort 0.241 0.216 -0.086 0.241 0.670 1.000 -0.759dusslope -0.062 0.040 0.091 -0.070 -0.025 -0.759 1.000

Table 6: Correlation table of the explanatory variables

5.4 Granger causality

To determine the direction of causality between two related stationary variables, Granger

(1969) suggests a testable definition of causality. The test basically assumes that the

information relevant to the forecast of the pair of variables is solely contained in the time

series data on these variables (Gujarati, 1995). We can say that y does not Granger-

39

Page 42: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

cause x if for all s > 0 the mean squared error of a forecast of xs+t based on (xt, xt−1, ...)

is the same as the mean squared error of a forecast of xt+s that uses both (xt, xt−1, ...)

and (yt, yt−1, ...). However, the existence of ”Granger causality”does not imply that y

is the result or the result of x. In case of non-stationary and cointegrated variables, a

error correction model can be used to determine the Granger causality (see Koop, 2000).

Gujarati (1995) distinguishes three cases of causality:

1. Unidirectional causality exists if the set of estimated coefficients indicates that

just one of the variables has lagged values which include statistically significant

information when the other variable is dependent in the regression equation.

2. Feedback or bilateral causality occurs if both variables are statistically significantly

different from zero in both regression equations.

3. Independence describes the case when the other variable can not help improving

the forecast of the dependent series.

Table 7 shows all the results of the pairwise granger causality tests with lags 2 and 4. For

each macroeconomic variable, there are two rows of results. The first of these two rows

shows the probability according to the F- statistic for the null hypothesis ”macroeco-

nomic variable does not (Granger-)cause the yield variable”. The second row includes

the probability for the null ”yield variable does not (Granger-)cause the macroeconomic

variable”.

The output of the tests provides some evidence about possible causality relationships.

There is strong statistical evidence that all yield variables are (Granger-)causing dcpi.

This would suggest that there is indeed some kind of fisher effect (see section in Germany

3.1). Additionally, the relationship between the yield variables and dcpi is unidirectional

from the yield variables to dcpi. The tests indicate a feedback relationship from the yield

variables to the gdp and ifo time series. Interestingly, only the short end of the curve

and the slope variables seems to have a bilateral relationship with the due series. As one

would expect, the lagged duslong time series includes statistical significant information

for all the yield variables if they are dependent in the regression equation. dfiscal, dfxrate,

drealfx, doil and djapanlong do not contain any statistical significant information.

To summarize, duslong is the only macroeconomic variable which clearly

(Granger-)causes the term structure. In the other direction, yield variables seem to

have an impact on dcpi, ifo and gdp.

40

Page 43: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

dyrs

10dyrs

5dyr1

mth

s3sl

ope1

0yrs

1yr

slop

e10y

rs3m

ths

Lag

s2

42

42

42

42

42

4

yie

ld9

dcp

i0.

099

0.19

30.

003

0.02

50.

000

0.00

00.

016

0.00

00.

032

0.00

20.

016

0.01

2dcp

i9

yie

ld0.

629

0.78

60.

588

0.55

80.

865

0.81

60.

538

0.57

80.

624

0.29

50.

175

0.36

4yie

ld9

gdp

0.09

60.

022

0.01

60.

004

0.00

50.

001

0.00

40.

034

0.00

50.

168

0.00

20.

084

gdp

9yie

ld0.

484

0.74

90.

448

0.77

90.

019

0.05

20.

010

0.00

50.

003

0.00

30.

007

0.00

9yie

ld9

ifo

0.11

00.

066

0.33

30.

017

0.15

90.

043

0.00

20.

263

0.06

20.

410

0.00

80.

449

ifo

9yie

ld0.

479

0.08

90.

151

0.06

30.

007

0.01

70.

000

0.00

30.

007

0.03

50.

002

0.00

5yie

ld9

due

0.29

60.

435

0.24

00.

438

0.53

20.

590

0.00

30.

025

0.03

70.

181

0.01

30.

060

due

9yie

ld0.

865

0.37

80.

638

0.23

20.

123

0.08

00.

159

0.20

20.

110

0.09

90.

083

0.14

7yie

ld9

dfisc

al0.

700

0.11

70.

633

0.90

50.

913

0.90

70.

539

0.54

30.

355

0.14

30.

535

0.26

1dfisc

al9

yie

ld0.

793

0.97

10.

633

0.90

50.

340

0.67

00.

915

0.98

00.

641

0.92

40.

982

0.99

9yie

ld9

dfx

rate

0.61

00.

659

0.85

80.

755

0.33

30.

682

0.40

40.

864

0.60

10.

807

0.34

80.

939

dfxra

te9

yie

ld0.

779

0.48

70.

858

0.75

50.

381

0.88

20.

670

0.93

40.

611

0.72

60.

451

0.67

9yie

ld9

dre

alfx

0.51

40.

505

0.35

50.

515

0.56

00.

700

0.28

10.

255

0.22

30.

465

0.42

70.

452

dre

alfx

9yie

ld0.

939

0.95

30.

355

0.51

50.

313

0.50

50.

060

0.18

90.

134

0.34

00.

041

0.09

6yie

ld9

doi

l0.

485

0.10

40.

942

0.41

20.

613

0.29

30.

799

0.39

70.

805

0.87

90.

963

0.26

7doi

l9

yie

ld0.

910

0.74

80.

942

0.41

20.

945

0.66

60.

264

0.69

40.

529

0.78

50.

074

0.22

1yie

ld9

dja

pan

long

0.32

30.

034

0.97

80.

526

0.63

10.

778

0.48

40.

686

0.98

30.

994

0.50

40.

998

dja

pan

long

9yie

ld0.

925

0.64

20.

978

0.52

60.

632

0.31

70.

709

0.30

90.

618

0.27

50.

533

0.21

9yie

ld9

dusl

ong

0.23

00.

307

0.30

80.

609

0.52

00.

610

0.99

70.

875

0.98

70.

958

0.91

00.

956

dusl

ong

9yie

ld0.

045

0.12

50.

103

0.32

00.

031

0.20

20.

010

0.06

70.

070

0.31

90.

035

0.08

4

Tab

le7:

Gra

nge

rpai

rwis

eca

usa

lity

test

s

41

Page 44: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

6 Empirical analysis

This chapter is the main part of this thesis and covers the empirical analysis of the re-

lationship between the yield curve and macroeconomic variables. Firstly, autoregressive

moving-average models are estimated. In the second step, a conventional OLS regression

is applied in order to find out which variables drive the yield curves. The fusion of the

uni- and multivariate model is implemented with the VARMA model. Furthermore, the

forecasting quality of the autoregressive models is backtested. In order to investigate

whether the explanatory power of different macroeconomic variables changes over time,

a ’moving’ estimation is used. The ’moving’ estimation computes the coefficients for a

10 year period and will move from the oldest available time frame to the most recent

one. In the last section, (G)ARCH models are employed.

6.1 Autoregressive Moving Average Processes

Univariate models are basically attempting to model and to predict data using only

information contained in their own past values and possibly current and past values of

an error term (Koop, 2000). Autoregressive models depend only upon the values that

the variable took in previous periods plus an error term. An AR(p) model with p lags

can be formulated as

yt = µ + β1yt−1 + β + ... + βpyt−p + εt

where εt is white noise which is independently and identically distributed (iid) with

E(ut) = 0 and V ar(ut) = σ2 (see Brooks, 2002). The moving average process MA(q) is

a qth order moving average mode.

yt = µ + εt + θ1εt−1 + ... + θqεt−q

The term is essentially a linear combination of white noise processes, so that yt depends

on the current and previous values of ε.

Extending the model with further explanatory variables, leads to a vector autoregressive

moving average (VARMA) process (see Lutkepohl, 1993). Thus, the model for yt with p

autoregressive terms, q moving average terms and r explanatory variables (in addition

to the autoregressive term) has the following shape (this equation is just for the first

42

Page 45: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

explanatory variable).

yt = µ+β1yt−1+ ...+βpyt−p+β1,1x1,t−1+ ...+β1,px1,t−p+ ...+βr,1xr,t−1+ ...+βr,pxr,t−p+εt

and

εt = ut + θ1ut−1 + ... + θqut−q

Although univariate ARMA with small values of p or q seems to be quite simple at first

glance, they can sometimes produce better out-of-sample forecasts than large macro-

econometric models (see Hamilton, 1994).

6.2 The Box-Jenkins Methodology

The Box-Jenkins methodology is a procedure to estimate an ARMA in a systematic

manner and it basically includes three or four steps:

1. Identification

2. Estimation

3. Diagnostic checking

4. Forecasting (see section 6.5)

Identification involves determining the order of the model required which means deter-

mining the appropriate values for p, q and d. This is done by using graphical procedures

which are called correlogram. The correlograms are the result of the autocorrelation

function (acf) and the partial autocorrelation function (pcf). The autocorrelation func-

tion is computed out of the sample covariance at lag k, γk, and the sample variance,

γ0

γk =

∑(yt − y)(yt+k − y)

nand γ0 =

∑(yt − y)2

n(15)

where n is the sample size and y is the sample mean. With γk and γ0, we can define the

sample autocorrelation function at lag k which is the ratio of the sample covariance to

sample variance.

ρk =γk

γ0

(16)

43

Page 46: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Similarly, the partial autocorrelation funcion ρkk measures the correlation between an

observation k lags ago and the current observation, after removing the effects of observa-

tions at intermediate periods (i.e. from yt+1 to yt−k+1). However, it is mostly difficult to

use graphical plots in order to identify the appropriate model, because the correlograms

of real data do barely exhibit the typical patterns. Therefore, information criteria are

used to identify the correct lag selection. In figure 11, the correlograms for dyrs10, dyr1

and slope10y1y are plotted . The first difference of the data has to be taken for the model

because stationarity is desirable in ARMA models. In chapter 5.2, the null hypothesis

of the adf test is rejected for all time series i.e. the data is stationary. Non-stationary

coefficients have the property that previous values of the error term keeps on effecting

the current value of yt as time progresses. As expected, there is no distinct pattern in

the diagrams and it seems as only the 1st lag is statistically significant. Interpreting

the correlogram would thus lead to an AR(1) model without a moving average term.

However, the explanatory power of the correlogram seems to be limited.

Hence in the second step estimation, different models are estimated and computed so

that the correlation and information criterion can be compared. Every combination

with up to AR(5) and MA(5) processes is estimated which leads to 35 different options.

In table 8, the results of the estimation are displayed with the adjusted R2 and the

Schwarz information criterion (SIC) for every model with up to AR(2) and MA(2)

terms (the Akaike criterion is also computed but not included in the table, it will also

not be discussed further due to its preference for models with a higher number of

parameters). All the models are estimated without a constant because the t-statistic of

the constant parameter does not indicate statistical significance and the coefficients are

close to zero. A R2 with an asterisk indicates that the model has the highest correlation

for the chosen time series. The other asterisk marks the model with the lowest figure

for the information criteria (see Gujarati, 1995).

Only in 2 out of 6 cases, the model with the highest R2 has also the lowest information

criterion but the values of the SIC are very close to each other for every time series

wherefore it is reasonable to use the adjusted R2 as an information criterion. In 5

out of the 6 models, the highest R2 is obtained if either only AR terms or only MA

terms are employed in the equation. If the estimations with up to five autoregressive

and five moving-average terms are also taken into account, the results slightly change.

For dyrs10, the ARMA(0,1) still has the lowest SIC, but the highest R2 (0.232) can be

achieved with (4,3) combination. This is similar in the case of dyrs5. The ARMA(0,1)

44

Page 47: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

has the lowest SIC, whereas the highest R2(0.193) is an ARMA(4,5)-model. An increased

number of parameters improves significantly the adjusted R2 of dyr1. With (5,5) terms,

the correlation goes up to 0.315 compared to 0.203 in the (0,2)-model. The R2 improves

only marginally by 1.5%, but, as opposed to the previous models where the lowest

SIC only included a low number of ARMA terms, the SIC dmths3 is the lowest for an

ARMA(4,3). Lastly, the slope time series dslope1y10y and dslope3m10y are tested. In

both cases, higher order models outperform the results of table 8 in terms of correlation

and the SIC. For dslope1y10y, the R2 doubles if an ARMA(4,4)-model is employed and

the lowest SIC is obtained with three AR and two MA terms. The highest R2(0.329)

for dslope3m10y is attained with a (3,3)ARMA-model and the SIC is minimised with

an ARMA(4,3) (for the higher lag order results see also table 13). In conclusion, we can

say that best models in terms of the information criterion can have a high as well as

a low number of parameters depending on the series although the SIC is the criterion

which has a stiff penalty term Brooks (2002).

The results indicate that the lower the maturity of the term structure, the higher is

the fit of the model in terms of R2 (merely dyrs5 does not confirm this trend). This

observation contrasts with the estimation in chapter 6.3, where the outcome was exactly

in the opposite if one looks at the correlation. It leads to the possible conclusion that

models for higher maturity paper should preferably be multivariate, whereas models for

dyr1 and dmths3 better perform if they are univariate.

After the estimation of the parameters, the model has to be validated and checked with

diagnostic checking. Diagonistic checking essentially means testing for autocorrelation.

If the residuals are white noise, the particular fit can be accepted. The Ljung-Box (LB)

statistic is a simple test in order to test the joint hypothesis that all m of the correlation

coefficients ρk are simultaneously equal to zero. Basically, it validates the linear inde-

pendence in time series. The LB statistic is approximately chi-square distributed (see

Hamilton, 1994).

LB = T (T + 2)m∑

k=1

ρ2k

T − k∼ χ2

m (17)

The computation of the LB statistics for all the models which are investigated in table

8 are displayed in table 9, additionally the Q-statistics for an ARMA(3,3),(4,4) and

(5,5) are computed. As the series represents the residuals from ARIMA estimation, the

appropriate degrees of freedom are adjusted to represent the number of autocorrelations

less the number of AR and MA terms previously estimated. For each model, we have

45

Page 48: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

chosen a set of two lags, one shorter lag and one longer lag. According to the Q-

statistics, the joint null hypothesis of the autocorrelation coefficients being jointly zero

can be rejected for all the analysed residuals, as the p-value of the Q-statistic is not

close to one in any case. However, there is also barely clear evidence for strong serial

correlation, i.e. p-values which are zero, and it seems as there is no possibility to avoid

autocorrelation in these ARIMA estimations. Adding more ARMA parameters to the

equation does not lower the LB statistics. Taking the 2nd difference of the time series

does lower the information content and autocorrelation is still present.

dyrs10 dyrs5 dyr1AR MA Adj. R2 SIC Adj. R2 SIC Adj. R2 SIC

1 0 0.112 0.878 0.100 1.258 0.154 1.754∗0 1 0.156∗ 0.847∗ 0.129∗ 1.245∗ 0.200 1.8112 0 0.118 0.906 0.097 1.292 0.163 1.7790 2 0.151 0.883 0.124 1.281 0.203∗ 1.8451 1 0.140 0.875 0.112 1.274 0.176 1.7572 1 0.137 0.914 0.113 1.304 0.181 1.7871 2 0.137 0.909 0.108 1.308 0.170 1.7942 2 0.131 0.951 0.113 1.333 0.175 1.824

dmths3 dslope1y10y dslope3m10yAR MA Adj. R2 SIC Adj. R2 SIC Adj. R2 SIC

1 0 0.276 1.905 0.136 1.021∗ 0.178 1.9000 1 0.280 2.112 0.163 1.099 0.196 2.0342 0 0.247 1.906 0.154 1.038 0.159 1.8940 2 0.410∗ 1.941 0.164 1.127 0.255∗ 1.9871 1 0.282 1.927 0.160 1.023 0.176 1.9322 1 0.306 1.854∗ 0.175∗ 1.042 0.251 1.809∗

1 2 0.277 1.963 0.157 1.055 0.223 1.9032 2 0.280 1.920 0.172 1.076 0.233 1.862

Table 8: ARMA Models

46

Page 49: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Figure 11: ACF and PACF (10 lags) for dyrs10, dyr1 and slope10y1y

47

Page 50: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

dyrs10 dyrs 5 dyr1AR MA Lag Q-stat. Prob. Q-stat. Prob. Q-stat. Prob.

1 0 2 4.877 0.027 2.833 0.092 2.909 0.08810 18.617 0.029 15.686 0.074 7.798 0.555

0 1 2 0.406 0.524 0.251 0.617 2.355 0.12510 10.270 0.329 10.364 0.322 6.064 0.733

2 0 3 4.249 0.039 3.162 0.075 2.684 0.10110 15.052 0.058 13.319 0.101 6.972 0.540

0 2 3 1.019 0.313 1.141 0.285 2.980 0.08410 8.995 0.343 9.004 0.342 6.463 0.596

1 1 3 0.599 0.439 0.742 0.389 0.910 0.34010 9.561 0.297 8.965 0.345 6.149 0.631

2 1 4 0.360 0.549 0.404 0.525 1.372 0.24110 9.633 0.210 9.234 0.236 4.260 0.749

1 2 4 1.094 0.296 1.191 0.275 1.256 0.26210 9.323 0.230 9.874 0.196 5.985 0.542

2 2 5 6.138 0.013 3.538 0.060 1.679 0.19510 9.171 0.164 6.530 0.367 4.212 0.648

3 3 10 3.698 0.448 7.559 0.109 5.926 0.20520 14.671 0.401 20.616 0.112 17.694 0.221

4 4 10 4.296 0.117 3.450 0.178 5.477 0.06520 14.122 0.293 16.614 0.165 20.467 0.059

5 5 11 7.273 0.007 3.079 0.079 5.211 0.02220 13.859 0.180 12.514 0.252 11.020 0.356

dmths3 dslope1y10y dslope3m10yAR MA Lag Q-stat. Prob. Q-stat. Prob. Q-stat. Prob.

1 0 2 1.241 0.265 2.119 0.146 0.935 0.33410 11.437 0.247 11.611 0.236 8.009 0.533

0 1 2 3.497 0.061 4.278 0.039 0.613 0.43410 17.325 0.044 13.835 0.128 14.530 0.105

2 0 3 3.000 0.083 0.433 0.510 3.153 0.07610 11.579 0.171 12.819 0.118 11.221 0.190

0 2 3 4.765 0.029 2.103 0.147 4.584 0.03210 7.879 0.445 9.810 0.279 9.276 0.320

1 1 3 1.310 0.252 0.177 0.674 1.169 0.28010 10.039 0.262 11.482 0.176 8.015 0.432

2 1 4 7.526 0.006 2.834 0.092 7.163 0.00710 9.056 0.249 10.081 0.184 8.688 0.276

1 2 4 8.768 0.003 0.660 0.416 1.359 0.24410 10.059 0.185 13.687 0.057 3.120 0.874

2 2 5 12.092 0.001 2.183 0.140 12.453 0.00010 12.752 0.047 9.643 0.140 18.113 0.006

3 3 10 7.143 0.129 5.791 0.215 13.098 0.01120 19.093 0.161 15.076 0.373 23.312 0.055

4 4 10 6.2505 0.044 6.896 0.032 7.565 0.02320 17.184 0.143 18.991 0.089 16.795 0.157

5 5 11 3.603 0.058 4.113 0.043 3.4793 0.06220 19.487 0.034 16.816 0.079 9.3607 0.498

Table 9: Q-statistics (Ljung-Box)

6.3 OLS estimation

To continue the analysis, it is useful to compute an ordinary least square estimation for

every yield variable using the macroeconomic variables which we discussed in chapter

3 as explanatory variables. Table 10 provides the coefficients, the t-statistics and the

48

Page 51: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

adjusted R2 of the regression. For the external interest rates from Japan and the US,

the appropriate variables are chosen so that they match the regressand. The long-term

yields (dyrs10 and dyrs5 ) are explained with duslong and djapanlong, the short end

(dyr1 and dmths3 ) matches with dusshort and djapanshort and the slope variables are

regressed on the difference of the foreign long and short time series.

Dep. Var. dyrs10 dyrs5 dyr1Expl. Var β t-Stat. β t-Stat. β t-Stat.dcpi 0.002 0.031 0.002 0.031 0.095 1.024dgdp -0.015 -0.794 -0.017 -0.762 0.002 0.053difo 0.028 2.447 0.039 2.824 0.014 0.627due -0.158 -1.767 -0.249 -2.331 -0.491 -2.801drealfx 0.013 1.014 -0.005 -0.360 -0.034 -1.483dfiscal 0.004 1.213 0.002 0.588 0.000 -0.033doil 0.011 1.235 0.014 1.329 0.048 3.122djapan 0.269 4.232 0.356 4.700 0.113 1.485dus 0.311 6.464 0.322 5.612 0.229 3.923Adj. R2 0.520 0.540 0.336SIC 0.460 0.816 1.738

Dep. Var. dmths3 dslope1y10y dslope3m10yExpl. Var β t-Stat. β t-Stat. β t-Stat.dcpi 0.134 1.318 -0.064 -0.873 -0.104 -1.047dgdp -0.012 -0.311 0.004 0.140 0.001 0.034difo -0.024 -0.984 0.015 0.866 0.055 2.381due -0.602 -3.116 0.296 2.230 0.343 1.906drealfx -0.005 -0.184 0.034 1.883 0.003 0.140dfiscal -0.002 -0.296 0.003 0.646 0.005 0.736doil 0.044 2.582 -0.023 -1.986 -0.019 -1.220djapan 0.140 1.677 0.044 0.719 0.189 2.281dus 0.157 2.438 0.147 2.501 0.165 2.073Adj. R2 0.242 0.137 0.137SIC 1.932 1.253 1.860

Table 10: OLS estimations for the yield variables (Period: 1975Q1-2005Q3)

The overview of these results gives a first indication in which direction macroeconomic

data tends to influence yields of different maturities.

As the theory suggest, the inflation rate has a positive influence on yields. The shorter

the maturity, the statistical significance of the price level rises and the βs also increase.

Long-term nominal yields are strongly influenced by expectations about future inflation,

49

Page 52: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

however it seems as the current inflation level only has a very small impact on the long

end and is not statistically significant in terms of the t-statistics. Consequently, the

slope of the curve gets tighter when inflation is going up.

There are three variables which characterise economic growth: dgdp, difo and due.

dgpd and difo are going in the same direction, i.e. an increase of the variable implies

economic growth and a diminishing Ifo or gdp points at a recession, whereas the

indication mechanism of the unemployment is working in the opposite way. According

to the t-statistics, the statistical significance of the Ifo index compared to the GDP

growth is higher for every equation and the βs of the GDP are not always indicating

the theorictically assumed sign. The β of the Ifo for the 3-months is negative which is

not the expected sign but for all the other yield parameter it is positive. Surprisingly,

the unemployment rate is a very strong explanatory when it is used for the yield level.

For the curve slope, this variable would be expected to move in the opposite direction

(lower unemployment rate indicates higher growth and therefore a steepening curve,

see chapter 3.2), but it moves in line with the spread between short and long rates.

The effect of drealfx and dfiscal on the term structure is not consistent and not

statistically significant, whereas doil has a positive impact on yield levels and a negative

on the term spread.

The foreign interest rates from Japan and the US have by far the largest coefficients,

which means that their influence on the German yields is extremely strong. If the

Japanese and US long-term rates rise by one percent and all the other explanatory

variables are fixed, dyrs10 gains 0.58%. The βs become smaller as the maturity

decreases. This might hint at the fact that the long end of the cure is more integrated

globally and the short end, which is driven by the independent monetary of each

country or monetary system, is therefore less correlated with foreign interest rates.

The adjusted R2 is decreasing as the maturity gets shorter. Especially for the slope

variable, the correlation is very low.

Butter and Jansen (2004) conduct a similar exercise for the German long-term interest

rate (10-years Bund) over the period from 1982Q1 to 2001Q4. Their results are quite

similar and they also find out that the Japanese and US interest rate have the strongest

impact on long-term rates in Germany. Additionally, their equation contains a long-run

element which is the regression output of the level data. As the additional long-run

coefficient does not improve the adjusted R2 in this estimation, it is not necessary to

include the term.

50

Page 53: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Finally, the variables with the five lowest t-statistics are dropped (see table 11) and

compared to the results of table 10. Table 12 documents which variables are chosen

for the different regressand. The adjusted R2 only decreases significantly for dmths3

by 6%. Therefore, one can conclude that the calculated correlation from the first OLS

estimation is only due to the input of the most significant regressors.

Dep. Var. dyrs10 dyrs5 dyr1Expl. Var β t-Stat. β t-Stat. β t-Stat.dvar1 0.021 2.048 0.032 2.757 -0.528 -3.284dvar2 -0.197 -2.388 -0.271 -2.809 0.043 2.917dvar3 0.306 5.179 0.396 5.703 0.131 1.897dvar4 0.320 6.851 0.359 6.543 0.287 4.991Adj. R2 0.512 0.536 0.336SIC 0.351 0.708 1.721

Dep. Var. dmths3 dslope1y10y dslope3m10yExpl. Var β t-Stat. β t-Stat. β t-Stat.dvar1 -0.702 -3.214 0.291 2.429 0.072 2.875dvar2 0.010 0.490 0.033 1.939 0.516 2.535dvar3 0.158 1.683 -0.023 -1.991 0.107 1.134dvar4 0.262 3.355 0.128 2.275 0.254 2.687Adj. R2 0.183 0.145 0.142SIC 2.335 1.071 2.196

Table 11: OLS estimations with four explanatory variables

dyrs10 dyrs5 dyr1 dmths3 dslope1y10y dslope 3m10ydvar1 difo difo due due due difodvar2 due due doil doil drealfx duedvar3 djapanlong djapanlong djapanshort djapanshort doil djapanslopedvar4 duslong duslong dusshort dusshort dusslope dusslope

Table 12: Explanatory variables

This section should have given an idea how intense the macroeconomy is steering the

term structure and which are the main drivers for different maturities. The following

sections will deepen the analysis.

51

Page 54: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

6.4 VARMA modelling

After the estimation of a pure univariate models in section 6.2 and a multivariate model

in section 6.3, we will merge both models for a so called vector autoregressive moving-

average (VARMA) model (see section 6.1). Vector autoregressive models were introduced

by Sims (1980) and have been very popular since then due to their flexibility and the

”a theoritical”approach. In this section, the estimation is not truly a VARMA models

because only the yield and slope variables are dependent in the OLS but it combines

univariate and multivariate parameters such as VARMA models do.

In section 6.2, we selected the best-fitting ARMA model (with up to two and five, respec-

tively, ARMA terms) according to the Schwarz information criterion and the adjusted

R2. For each time series, the ARMA model with lowest SIC and the highest R2 for up

to two and five ARMA terms is taken. If the additional ARMA terms do not result in

a higher R2 or lower SIC, only the models with up to two ARMA terms are considered.

Since in some cases, additional parameters produce higher R2 or lower SIC, these models

are accordingly estimated. There is also the possibility (see dyrs10 and dyrs5 ) that the

highest R2 and lowest SIC match in one model. In table 12, the four macroeconomic

variables with the highest statistical significance for each yield series in the OLS esti-

mation are specified. The autoregressive terms of these four variables are included with

no, one or two lags in the uni-/multivariate models. This procedure leads to between

6 and 12 models per series: The best-fitting (according to SIC and the adjusted R2)

models out of table 8 with no, one or two lags of macroeconomic variables combined

with the best ARMA models with up to five AR and MA terms with no, one or two lags

of macroeconomic variables.

The goal of this exercise is to determine whether the macroeconomic data delivers addi-

tional information to the autoregressive estimation. Table 13 summarises all the results.

The examination of the results shows that the additional macroeconomic variables can

have ambiguous effects. For the long end of the curve (dyrs10 and dyrs5 ), autoregres-

sive macroeconomic variables do neither improve the correlation nor the information

criterion. Therefore, you can conclude that if the estimation is done with lagged terms,

it is optimal to choose an univariate model. The outcome for the further variable is

not so distinct. Adding the first lag of macroeconomic variables to the univariate dyr1

models yields for the (1,0)- and (0,2)-model to a better models in terms of correlation

and the selection criterion. However, two lags of macroeconomic variables do not make

sense as the SIC increases and correlation only slightly rises. For dmths3, an ARMA(2,1)

52

Page 55: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

and (3,2)-model enhances the R2 and the SIC if the multivariate equation is employed

(with the first lag of macroeconomic variables). Additional variables do not help in the

other investigated models for dmths3, as either the R2 does not significantly pick up

or the information criteria drops. Still, univariate short-rate models partially improve

when multivariate parameters are added. Finally, the slope time series are analysed.

The multivariate case only improves ARMA(1,0) for dslope1y10y and ARMA(2,1) for

dslope3m10y.

Altogether, we can conclude that multivariate models can be useful if we have only a

few ARMA terms and are especially well working at the short end of the curve, whereas

they are less helpful for the long-term interest rates and the yield spread.

Expl. Variables dyrs10 Expl. Variables dyrs5AR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC AR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC

0 1 0.156 0.847 0 1 0.129 1.2450 1 1 Lag 0.135 0.970 0 1 1 Lag 0.129 1.3430 1 2 Lags 0.123 1.109 0 1 2 Lags 0.114 1.4814 3 0.232 0.756 4 5 0.193 1.3944 3 1 Lag 0.204 1.057 4 5 1 Lag 0.220 1.4784 3 2 Lags 0.197 1.184 4 5 2 Lags 0.214 1.614

Expl. Variables dyr1 Expl. Variables dmths3AR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC AR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC

1 0 0.154 1.754 0 2 0.410 1.9411 0 1 Lag 0.256 1.750 0 2 1 Lag 0.339 1.9631 0 2 Lags 0.255 1.877 0 2 2 Lags 0.396 1.9230 2 0.197 1.845 2 1 0.306 1.8540 2 1 Lag 0.261 1.767 2 1 1 Lag 0.428 1.7850 2 2 Lags 0.268 1.882 2 1 2 Lags 0.417 1.8385 5 0.315 1.840 3 2 0.417 1.7445 5 1 Lag 0.313 1.973 3 2 1 Lag 0.455 1.7115 5 2 Lags 0.409 1.943 3 2 2 Lags 0.470 1.759

n.a. n.a. 3 3 0.426 1.759n.a. n.a. 3 3 1 Lag 0.437 1.773n.a. n.a. 3 3 2 Lags 0.485 1.759

Expl. Variables dslope1y10y Expl. Variables dslope3m10yAR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC AR MA Macro Adj. R2 SIC

1 0 0.136 1.021 0 2 0.255 1.9871 0 1 Lag 0.228 0.997 0 2 1 Lag 0.219 1.9971 0 2 Lags 0.264 1.072 0 2 2 Lags 0.304 1.9432 1 0.175 1.042 2 1 0.251 1.8092 1 1 Lag 0.219 1.069 2 1 1 Lag 0.335 1.8142 1 2 Lags 0.288 1.086 2 1 2 Lags 0.305 1.8113 2 0.320 0.914 3 3 0.329 1.7933 2 1 Lag 0.320 0.978 3 3 1 Lag 0.270 1.8303 2 2 Lags 0.360 1.043 3 3 2 Lags 0.265 1.8454 4 0.348 0.963 4 3 0.273 1.7374 4 1 Lag 0.310 1.087 4 3 1 Lag 0.181 1.8654 4 2 Lags 0.371 1.085 4 3 2 Lags 0.290 1.850

Table 13: VARMA models

53

Page 56: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

6.5 Forecasting

One of the advantages of the models which are discussed in section 6.2 and 6.4 is that

they provide an easy framework for forecasting models. Therefore, the best performing

models of the mentioned section are used to produce in-sample and out-of-sample fore-

casts. In-sample forecasts estimate the parameters over the whole sample period. This

method measures the average relationship over the entire period and produces a forecast

with information that was not available at the time when the forecast was computed

(e.g. calculate a forecast for 1995Q1 using the estimation for the period from 1975Q1

to 2005Q3). On the other hand, out-of-sample models only use observations which we

were actually available when the forecast was computed (e.g. forecasting a variable for

1995Q1 with a sample from 1975Q1 to 1994Q4). In this section, two kinds of out-of-

sample models are employed. Firstly, a time frame forecast, which always uses the same

number of observations, i.e. keeps on increasing the start/end date by one observation

after each estimation (rolling time frame). Secondly, the sample period is extended

by one observation each time and the start date keeps identical (recursive time frame).

Usually, one would expect that in-sample outperform out-of-sample models because they

include more information (Brooks, 2002).

As only 40 observations (10 years) are used for the rolling time frame forecast, the

number of parameters should be kept small in order to avoid overfitting due to a high

degrees of freedom. Therefore, only the maximum of two lags of autoregressive and

moving-average terms as well as only one lag of macroeconomic variables (chosen ac-

cording to table 12) are used to estimate the coefficients which makes it possible to

compare the performance of the three forecasting methods. The ARMA lag order is

selected according to table 13 (lag order with the highest R2 and lowest SIC). For the

rolling forecast, the first time frame is 1975Q1 to 1984Q4 so that the first forecast is

1985Q1 and the last is 2005Q3. The recursive forecast works out in the same manner

and starts with the sample period from 1975Q1 to 1984Q4, then subsequently adds one

observation. The in-sample forecast estimates the coefficients for the whole sample and

also computes the predictions from 1985Q1 to 2005Q3.

Only one period forecasting models are tested in this thesis because the quality of the

prediction significantly decreases if multi-period forecasts are conducted.

Table 14 summarises the results of the estimated forecasting models. For each ARMA

(one pure ARMA model and an ARMA model with macroeconomic variables) order,

three different forecasting models (rolling time frame, rol. ; recursive time frame, rec.

54

Page 57: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

and out-of-sample, out) are tested. In order to compare the models, two performance

indicators are computed. The first indicator simply measures whether the forecast went

in the correct direction. The absolute error is the sum of the absolute value of the dif-

ference between the observed and the forecasted variables. Therefore, it is desirable to

minimise the absolute error.

For every estimated model, more than the half of the predicted values went in the correct

direction which shows that these forecasting models are generally working. As already

mentioned in the first paragraph of this chapter, the time frame (in-sample) model

should perform worst, whereas the out-of-sample estimation should be the best model

according to the theory. The absolute error, which can be regarded as the more exact

gauge compared to the direction indicator, verifies this behaviour in the vast majority of

the tested ARMA orders, i.e. the absolute error is the highest for the rolling time frame

models and the lowest for the out-of-sample models. However, the amount of forecasts

in the correct direction does not necessarily originate from the out-of-sample model, in

approximately half of the cases an in-sample model outperforms the out-of-sample model

in terms of the direction prediction.

Adding the macroeconomic variables to the forecasting equation does not enhance the

quality of the prediction (with the exception of dyrs5 where the addition of the macro-

economic term significantly improves the forecast). The absolute error even increases

slightly in almost every ARMA model if the macroeconomic are attached to the equa-

tion.

The comparison of the results of the forecasts for the different time series shows that the

models for the slope variables are the best working ones with lowest absolute error. The

models for the long end (dyrs10 and dyrs5 ) are in the middle and the shorter maturities

(dyr1 and dmths3 ) are overall the worst working models in terms of the absolute error.

In table 14, we have used the highest adjusted R2 or the lowest SIC as the selection

criteria (for dyrs10 and dyrs5 the criteria chose the same ARMA order), but there is

no perceivable relationship between the quality of the forecast and the chosen selection

criterion.

55

Page 58: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Expl. Variables dyrs10 Expl. Variables dyrs5Model AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err. AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err.

rol. 0 1 57.83% 21.901 0 1 50.60% 27.683rec. 0 1 60.24% 21.378 0 1 53.01% 26.416out 0 1 59.04% 21.170 0 1 54.22% 26.264rol. 0 1 1 Lag 59.04% 23.036 0 1 1 Lag 67.47% 23.973rec. 0 1 1 Lag 60.24% 21.538 0 1 1 Lag 80.72% 19.201out 0 1 1 Lag 62.65% 20.751 0 1 1 Lag 89.16% 17.566

Expl. Variables dyr1 Expl. Variables dmths3Model AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err. AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err.

rol. 1 0 53.01% 27.401 0 2 63.86% 25.167rec. 1 0 53.01% 26.745 0 2 57.83% 27.271out 1 0 53.01% 26.700 0 2 57.83% 24.509rol. 1 0 1 Lag 56.63% 30.298 0 2 1 Lag 59.04% 30.429rec. 1 0 1 Lag 54.22% 29.382 0 2 1 Lag 65.06% 27.841out 1 0 1 Lag 57.83% 27.638 0 2 1 Lag 65.06% 25.053rol. 0 2 56.63% 28.038 2 1 62.65% 22.854rec. 0 2 54.22% 28.141 2 1 60.24% 22.918out 0 2 55.42% 27.361 2 1 63.86% 22.356rol. 0 2 1 Lag 51.81% 32.687 2 1 1 Lag 53.01% 31.676rec. 0 2 1 Lag 54.22% 29.782 2 1 1 Lag 65.06% 26.980out 0 2 1 Lag 55.42% 27.851 2 1 1 Lag 65.06% 26.201

Expl. Variables dslope1y10y Expl. Variables dslope3m10yModel AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err. AR MA Macro Dir. Abs. err.

rol. 1 0 73.49% 17.930 0 2 66.27% 21.441rec. 1 0 73.49% 18.098 0 2 63.86% 19.612out 1 0 73.49% 17.933 0 2 63.86% 19.618rol. 1 0 1 Lag 72.29% 20.028 0 2 1 Lag 61.45% 26.914rec. 1 0 1 Lag 67.47% 19.335 0 2 1 Lag 63.86% 22.385out 1 0 1 Lag 69.88% 16.762 0 2 1 Lag 72.29% 19.482rol. 2 1 77.11% 17.843 2 1 71.08% 20.467rec. 2 1 75.90% 18.239 2 1 63.86% 19.461out 2 1 71.08% 17.623 2 1 65.06% 19.334rol. 2 1 1 Lag 68.67% 23.671 2 1 1 Lag 60.24% 27.746rec. 2 1 1 Lag 66.27% 21.705 2 1 1 Lag 63.86% 25.126out 2 1 1 Lag 77.11% 17.039 2 1 1 Lag 67.47% 19.951

Table 14: Forecasting models

56

Page 59: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

6.6 Time frame estimation

This sections builds open chapter 6.3. The OLS estimation with the four most significant

variables is being repeated but a time frame estimation over 40 observations (10 years)

is applied. This exercise can demonstrate how the coefficient, t-statistics and correlation

changes over time, i.e. it is possible to gauge the influence of the different explanatory

variables.

The first estimation covers the time period from 1975Q1 to 1984Q4, then the frame

moves to 1975Q2-1985Q1 and so forth up to the last observation. A program which is

implemented in EViews automatically estimates each time frame and reads out the co-

efficients, the t-Statistics and the adjusted R2. The result of this process are the plots in

figure 12 to figure 17. Each of these series has 84 observations from 1984Q4 to 2005Q3.

Observing the trend of the correlation throughout the investigated period, one can recog-

nise that there are common trends among the different time series. In 1991 (right afer

the German reunification), the R2 reaches the peak for every dependent variable and the

t-Statistics for the majority of the explanatory variable also rise significantly during this

period. This period was characterised by an inverted yield curve with short-term rates

almost touching the 10% level. The inversion lasted from about 1991Q1 to 1994Q4. The

second powerful increase of the goodness-of-fit occurs from about 2001 on, when the ECB

started cutting rates and the low-yield era in Europe commenced. Another interesting

feature of the results is that the R2 of longer paper is much less volatile compared to the

shorter paper and the term spread. The range of the R2 of dyrs10 and dyrs5 is about

0.2, whereas the range of the R2 of dyr1, dmths3, slope1y10y and slope3m10y is more

than three times higher. The stability of the long-term rates estimation gives evidence

that the relationship between the long end and macroeconomic variables is more robust

in the long-run than the link between the short end as well as the slope which seems to

have a quite volatile connection with the macroeconomy.

It is also worth looking at the individual results. For both long yield time series (dyrs10

and dyrs5 ), the statistical significance and the coefficient of djapanlong decreases during

the observed period (see figure 12(a), 12(b), 13(a) and 12(b)). The opposite movement

is taken by duslong. The t-Statistics of due and difo for dyrs10 are trending similarly.

The next group is the short end of the curve (see figure 14 and 15). The two time

frame estimations exhibit very analogue outcomes. The doil coefficients drops and the

t-Statistic is rather volatile. In terms of the external interest rates, the effect of the

Japanese rates are overall slightly stronger than the US rates rate. The unemployment

57

Page 60: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

rate (due) is the only explanatory variable with a t-Statistic which never goes below

one. However, the influece of this variable approximately halves in the post reunifica-

tion period.

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 12: Time frame estimation for dyrs10

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 13: Time frame estimation for dyrs5

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 14: Time frame estimation for dyr1

58

Page 61: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 15: Time frame estimation for dmths3

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 16: Time frame estimation for dslope1y10y

(a) Coefficients (b) t-Statistics (c) Adjusted R2

Figure 17: Time frame estimation for dslope3m10y

Finally, the estimation is applied to the slope series dslope1y10y and dslope3m10y. The

phenomenon of the weakened effect of due after the reunification. Recently, the statis-

tical significane of dusslope has increased enormously which resulted in an increase of

correlation. Overall the link between the slope and the macroeconomy seems to be the

59

Page 62: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

weakest that is why the time frame estimation is difficult to interpret.

In conclusion, the time frame regression is an useful experiment but as each estimation

has only 40 observations, a few outliers might distort the results.

6.7 (G)ARCH modelling

One of the major problems when analysing financial data is volatility clustering. In

financial time series, volatility tends to appear in bunches which means that periods

with very high (low) volatility tend to follow periods with higher (low) volatility. The

result of this behaviour are volatility cluster, one could think of that as ’autocorrelated

volatility’ (Brooks, 2002). Another relevant stylized fact of financial data is the tendency

of financial asset returns to have distributions that exhibit heavy tails. In figure 18, the

graphs for the second order difference are plotted and the volatility cluster are readily

identifiable.

(a) ddyrs10 (b) ddmths3 (c) ddslope1y10y

Figure 18: The second difference time series of yrs10, mths3 and slope1y10y

The classical linear regression model (CLRM) essentially assumes that the error term εt

is normally distributed, i.e. the error have zero mean and the variance is constant and

finite over all values of xt.

yt = β1 + β2xt + εt where εt ∼ (0, σ2)

The assumption of the constant variance of the error terms is called homoscedasticity. If

the variance changes changes over time, this occurrence is known as hetroscedasticity. If

the errors are assumed to be homoscedastic, but are hetroscedastic, an implication would

be that standard error estimates might be wrong.

ARCH (Autoregressive conditionally heteroscedastic) modelling attempts to parame-

60

Page 63: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

terise the volatility clustering and the hetroscedastic behaviour of financial data. If the

errors have a zero mean, the below-mentioned can be assumed.

σ2t = var(εt|εt−1, εt−2, ...) = E[ε2

t |εt−1, εt−2, ...] (18)

Equation (18) states that the conditional variance of a zero mean normally distributed

random variable εt is equal to the conditional expected value of the square of εt. The

ARCH approach models the conditional variance of the error term, σ2, to depend on the

immediately pervious value of the squared error.

σ2t = α0 + α1ε

2t−1 (19)

This equation is also known as ARCH(1) model (the conditional variance depends on

one lagged squared error) and originates from Engle (1982). If the model is extended to

the general case, a ARCH(q) model is obtained where the error variance depends on q

lags of squared errors.

σ2t = α0 + α1ε

2t−1 + α2ε

2t−2 + ... + αqε

2t−q (20)

Despite offering a framework for the analysis of time series models of volatility, ARCH

models have barely been used due to a number of problems. There is no clear approach

to determine the value of q (number of lags of the squared residuals in the model).

The value of q might be very large in order to capture all of the dependence in the

conditional variance which might lead to a large conditional variance model that is not

parsimonious.

To solve these issues, Bollerslev (1986) introduced GARCH (Generalised ARCH) models.

The GARCH model extends Engle’s model with a term which allows the conditional

variance to be dependent upon previous lags (a moving-average component).

σ2t = α0 + α1ε

2t−1 + β1σ

2t−1 (21)

Equation (21) is known as a GARCH(1,1) model. If the model can be generalised with

q lags of squared errors and p lags pf the conditional variance.

σ2t = α0 +

q∑i=1

αiε2t−i +

q∑j=1

βjσ2t−j (22)

61

Page 64: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

The three terms specified in the equation can be interpreted as a weighted function of a

long-term average value (α0), information about volatility during the previous periods

(αiε2t−i) and the fitted variance from the model during the previous periods (βjσ

2t−j). The

advantage of GARCH over ARCH is that it is more parsimonious, and avoids overfitting.

Since σ2t is the conditional variance, its value must always be strictly positive, as the

squares of lagged errors are not negative by definition. Therefore, all the coefficients

are required to be non-negative. In case one or more coefficients would be negative,

the conditional might turn negative as well if there is a large lagged squared innovation

term. Thus, the sufficient condition for the coefficients is αi ≥ 0 ∀ i = 0, 1, 2, ..., q

The basic intention of ARCH/GARCH models is to correct the deficiencies of the ordi-

nary least square method by computing a prediction for the variance of each error term.

This prediction turns out often to be of interest for financial data. Since these meth-

ods are treating hetroscedasticity as a variance to be modelled and deal with the issues

of volatility clustering, they have become a commonly used tool for financial decision

concerning risk analysis, portfolio selection and derivative pricing (Engle, 2001).

6.7.1 ARCH LM Test

Engle (1982) suggests a Lagrange Multiplier test for ARCH effects in the residuals.

The specification of heteroskedasticity was motivated by the observation that in many

financial time series, the magnitude of residuals appeared to be related to the magnitude

of recent residuals.

The ARCH LM test statistic is computed from an auxiliary test regression. To test

the null hypothesis that there is no ARCH up to order q in the residuals, the following

regression is estimated:

ε2t = β0 + (

q∑i=1

βsε2t−i) + vt (23)

where ε is the residual. The regression is computed with the squared residuals on a

constant and lagged squared residuals up to order q. In EViews, two test statistics

are reported. The F-statistic is an omitted variable test for joint significance of all

lagged squared residuals. The Obs*R-squarded statistic is Engle’s LM test statistic,

computed as the number of observations times the R2 from the test regression. The

exact finite sample distribution of the F-statistic under H0 is not known but the LM

statistic is asymptotically distributed χ2(q) under quite general conditions. Table 15

presents the results of the ARCH LM test for the first differenced data. Overall, the

62

Page 65: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

dyrs10 dyrs5Lags F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob. F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob.

1 3.737 0.055 3.687 0.055 1.214 0.273 1.221 0.2692 2.516 0.085 4.954 0.084 0.669 0.514 1.356 0.5083 2.205 0.091 6.482 0.090 2.286 0.082 6.708 0.0824 2.119 0.083 8.247 0.083 3.726 0.007 13.817 0.0085 1.742 0.130 8.527 0.130 3.185 0.010 14.752 0.011

dyr1 dmths3Lags F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob. F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob.

1 2.665 0.105 2.651 0.103 29.992 0.000 24.644 0.0002 3.159 0.046 6.158 0.046 6.216 0.003 11.578 0.0033 2.866 0.039 8.297 0.040 17.560 0.000 38.082 0.0004 2.421 0.052 9.338 0.053 7.482 0.000 24.984 0.0005 1.915 0.097 9.308 0.097 5.561 0.000 23.676 0.000

dslope1y10y dslope3m10yLags F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob. F-stat Prob. Obs. R2 Prob.

1 0.664 0.417 0.671 0.413 34.950 0.000 27.839 0.0002 1.419 0.246 2.841 0.242 11.939 0.000 20.530 0.0003 1.274 0.286 3.828 0.281 42.253 0.000 64.456 0.0004 1.292 0.277 5.160 0.271 32.075 0.000 64.845 0.0005 0.821 0.537 4.167 0.526 8.573 0.000 33.103 0.000

Table 15: ARCH LM test statistics

null hypothesis can be cleary rejected in some cases, but there are also time series where

heteroskedasticity is not definitely evident. The presence of ARCH effects in dmths3 and

dslope3y10y is obvious. For all lags, the test statistic are highly significant. For dyr1

and dyrs10, the evidence is not as obvious as in the previously mentioned time series,

but the null is predominantly rejected at a confidence level of 90%. The results for dyrs5

are not clear. For one and two lagged squared error terms, the time series seems to

be homoskedastic, whereas for more than two lagged terms, autocorrelation probably

occurs. Finally, the test statistics of dslope1y10y do not indicate ARCH effects.

6.7.2 (G)ARCH model estimation

After the introduction to the concept of GARCH modelling and the confirmation of

the existence of ARCH effects in most models, the models are finally estimated and

63

Page 66: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

compared to the pure ARMA models.

In order to compare the restricted ARMA models with the unrestricted ARMA-GARCH

model, the previously measures (adjusted R2 and SIC) are used but likelihood ratio (LR)

tests are also performed. The likelihood ratio test is a hypothesis test which compares the

maximised values of the log-likelihood function (LLF) (assuming normally distributed

errors). The LR test statistic asymptotically follows a Chi-squared distribution

LR = −2(Lr − Lu) ∼ χ2m (24)

where m are the number of restrictions, Lu the LLF of the unrestricted model and Lr

the LLF of the restricted model. As the restricted residual sum of the square is always

at least as big as the unrestricted sum of squares, Lr ≤ Lu is always given.

In the (G)ARCH estimation, models with no or one lagged squared error (ARCH) terms

and no or up to five conditional variance (GARCH) terms are estimated combined with

a maximum of five ARMA lags. Like, in section 6.2, the ARMA parameters do not

include a constant.

In comparison to the pure linear ARMA estimation, the goal of the GARCH estimation

is to improve the SIC and to reject the null of the LR test (i.e. the unrestricted GARCH

model is superior to the pure ARMA model). It is important to note that the difference

of the Schwarz Criteria between the ARMA and the corresponding ARMA-GARCH

model with the equivalent ARMA lag order strongly correlates (above 99%) with LR

test for both models. The adjusted R2 is not used as a selection criterion because it

usually decreases when GARCH models are estimated and its information content is

limited (see Brooks, 2002). Table 16 presents the results for dyr1, dmths3, dslope1y10y

and dslope3m10y, as dyrs10 and dyrs5 do not improve when GARCH terms are added

to the equation, they are not documented in the table.

Although, there are a large number of LR test statistics for dyrs10 where the null can be

rejected, the SIC only marginally decreases for a GARCH(0,1) and GARCH(1,1) with ei-

ther ARMA(3,2) or ARMA(3,3) parameters. For these estimations, the p-value of the JB

statistic also indicates normally distributed residuals. In case of dyrs5, a GARCH(0,1)

model with an ARMA(2,3) or (2,4) is the only combination which fulfills both require-

ments and the residuals are normally distributed. In section 6.7.1, the ARCH LM test

already showed that there is no clear evidence for ARCH effects in dyrs10 and dyrs5,

which is confirmed by the just presented results.

Turning from the long end of the curve to the short end, GARCH models achieve sig-

64

Page 67: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

nificant drops in the SIC and the LR test heavily increases. For dyr1, a GARCH(1,1)

model extended with an ARMA(4,2) term performs best and if the ARMA order is lim-

ited to two lags, a GARCH(1,0) with ARMA(0,1) is chosen. A simple ARMA(0,1) with

a GARCH(1,2) process for dmths3 outperforms even models with higher lag orders. The

residuals of the dyr1 and dmths3 are clearly not gaussian distributed which questions

the validity of the LR tests.

Finally, the time series for the slope of the curve are studied. Although, the ARCH

LM test did not show any ARCH effects for dslope1y10y, the LR test strongly rejects

the null and the SIC improves by 0.5 for the best ARMA-GARCH (0,1)-(1,2). The

p-value of the JB statistic is pretty low but not as low as for the models for the shorter

maturities. Despite the presents of distinct ARCH effects, the GARCH estimation for

dslope3m10y does not perform better than for dslope1y10y, whereby the best model is

an ARMA-GARCH (0,1)-(1,1).

GARCH estimations are distinctly enhancing for some time series, as table 16 docu-

ments, even if the residuals are not normally distributed and the LR test therefore can

not be regarded as theoretical valid. However, the strong correlation of the LR test and

the difference of the SIC between the ARMA and ARMA-GARCH models gives evidence

that the outcome of the LR test is still relevant. A further analysis, which would go

beyond the scope of this master thesis, should therefore incorporate econometric models

with stable non-Gaussian variables (see Rachev and Mittnik, 2000, chapter 14).

Time series AR MA ARCH GARCH SIC R2 JB (p-value) LR stat.dyr1 4 2 1.854 0.212 0.000 41.941

4 2 1 1 1.636 0.270 0.0000 1 1.811 0.200 0.000 35.0430 1 1 0 1.616 0.186 0.000

dmths3 0 1 2.112 0.280 0.000 84.5180 1 1 2 1.611 0.256 0.000

dslope1y10y 0 1 2.112 0.280 0.000 84.4550 1 1 3 1.649 0.251 0.015

dslope3m10y 0 1 2.034 0.196 0.000 67.2940 1 1 2 1.629 0.176 0.716

Table 16: GARCH models

65

Page 68: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

7 Conclusions

This master thesis covered a very broad discussed area in economic and econometric

research. Certainly, the theoretical and empirical part of this essay could therefore only

analyse a small extract of possible research directions in the area.

In the literature review, a selection of some recent research about the relationship of yield

curve and macroeconomic variables was presented. In chapter 6, where the empirical

estimations and tests were summarised, the outcome provided some interesting results.

With the employed estimations, it is possible to quantify and compare the influence of

macroeconomic variables on different maturities of interest rates as well as the shape

(slope) of the yield curve. In the second step, univariate models were estimated and

compared versus multivariate models. In this context, a main conclusion is that univari-

ate models are far better for estimating short maturities and multivariate models should

be preferred for longer maturities (compare section 6.2 and 6.3). Forecasting models

performed satisfactory, but adding macroeconomic variables in the forecasting equation

did not notably improve the quality of the forecast. Lastly, an univariate GARCH es-

timation was computed and led to better fitting models for the short end of the curve

and the term spread.

Further research could focus on e.g. multivariate GARCH models or the reaction of the

term structure of interest rates after the occurrence of economic shocks.

66

Page 69: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Bibliography

Bange, M. (1996): Capital Markets Forecast of Economic Growth: New Test for Ger-many, Japan and the United States. Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics35, 3–17.

Barsky, R. and Kilian, L. (2004): Oil and the Marcoeconomy since the 1970s. CEPRDiscussion Paper.

Bernanke, B. and Mihov, I. (1997): What does the Bundesbank target? EuropeanEconomic Review 41, 1025–1053.

Bjørnland, H. (2000): The dynamic effects of aggregate demand, supply and oil priceshocks - a comparative study. The Manchester School 68(5), 578–607.

Bollerslev, T. (1986): Generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Journalof Econometrics 31, 307–327.

Bonser-Neal, C. and Morley, T. (1997): Does the Yield Spread Predict Real EconomicActivity? Multicountry Analysis. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, EconomicReview Third Quarter.

Brigo, D. and Mercurio, F. (2001): Interest Rate Models Theory and Practice. SpringerHeidelberg.

Brooks, C. (2002): Introductory econometrics for finance. Cambrigde University PressCambridge.

Butter, F. D. and Jansen, P. (2004): An empirical analysis of the German long-terminterest rate. Applied Financial Economics 14, 731–741.

Byeon, Y. and Ogaki, M. (1999): An Empirical Investigation of Exchange Rates andThe Term Structure of Interest Rates. Department of Economics Working Paper,University of Ohio 12(20), 495–508.

Cairns, A. (2004): Interest Rate Models. Princeton University Press Princeton.

Chinn, M. and Frankel, J. (2005): The Euro Area and World Interest Rates. Santa CruzCenter for International Economics, Working Paper Series (1016).

Clare, A. and Lekkos, I. (2000): An analysis of the relationship between internationalbond markets. Bank of England Working Paper (123).

Clostermann, J. and Schnatz, B. (2000): The determinants of the euro-dollar exchangerate. Discussion Paper Economic Research Group of the Deutsche Bundesbank (2).

Cooray, J. (2002): The Fisher Effect: A Review of the Literature. Macquarie EconomicsResearch Papers (6).

67

Page 70: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Correia-Nunes, J. and Stemitsiotis, L. (1995): Budget deficit and interest rates: Is therea link? International evidence. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics Vol. 57(4),425–449.

Cox, J., Ingersoll, J., and Ross, S. (1985): A Theory of the Term Structure of InterestRates. Econometrica 53(2), 385–407.

Culbertson, J. (1957): The Term Structure of Interest Rates. The Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 71(4), 485–517.

Decoudre, B. (2005): Fiscal Policy and Interest Rates. Document de Travail OFCE (5).

Deppner, C. (1992): Die Schatzung der Zinsstruktur und deren Bedeutung in der Kapi-talmarkttheorie. Rosch-Busch Hallstadt.

Dua, P., Raje, N., and Sahoo, S. (2004): Interest Rate Modeling and Forecasting inIndia. Centre for Development Economics.

Enders, W. (1995): Applied Econometric Time Series. John Wiley & Sons New York.

Engle, R. (1982): Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of thevariance of United Kingdom inflation. Econometrica 50(4), 987–1008.

Engle, R. (2001): GARCH 101: The Use of ARCH/GARCH Models in Applied Econo-metrics. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4), 157–168.

Engsted, T. and Tanggard, C. (2005): The comovement of US and German bond mar-kets. The Aarhuss School of Business.

Estrella, A. (2005): Why does the yield curve predict output and inflation? The Eco-nomic Journal 115, 722–744.

Fama, F. (1975): Short-term Interest Rates as Predictors of Inflation. The AmericanEconomic Review 65(3), 269–282.

Fisher, I. (1932): Die Zinstheorie. Gustav Fischer Jena.

Granger, C. (1969): Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods. Econometrica 37(3), 424–438.

Greene, W. (1997): Econometric Analysis. Prentice-Hall Upper Saddle River.

Gujarati, N. (1995): Basic econometrics. McGraw-Hill New York 3. ed. Edition.

Hamilton, J. (1994): Time Series Analysis. Princeton University Press New Jersey.

Harvey, C. (1991): The Term Structure and World Economic Growth. The Journal ofFixed Income 1, 4–17.

Hicks, J. (1950): Value and Capital. Clarendon Press Oxford second edition Edition.

68

Page 71: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Ho, T. and Lee, S. (1986): Term Structure Movements and Pricing Interest Rate Con-tingent Claims. Journal of Finance 41(5), 1011–1029.

Hubbard, R. (2002): Money and the Financial System, and the Economy. PearsonEducation Boston fourth edition Edition.

Hull, J. (1999): Options, Futures & Other Derivatives. Prentice Hall Upper SaddleRiver.

Hull, J. and White, A. (1990): Pricing interest-rate derivative securities. The Review ofFinancial Studies 3(4), 573–592.

Inci, A. and Lu, B. (2004): Exchange rates and interest rates: can term structure modelsexplain currency movements? Journal of Economics Dynamics & Control 28, 1595–1624.

Jimenez-Rodrıguez, R. and Sanchez, M. (2004): Oil price shocks and real GDP growth- Empirical evidence and for some OECD countries. European Central Bank workingpaper series (362).

Koop, G. (2000): Analysis of Economic Data. John Wiley & Sons New York.

LeBlanc, M. and Chinn, M. (2004): Do High Oil Prices Presage Inflation? The Evidencefrom G-5 Countries. University of California, Santa Cruz.

Leidermann, L. and Svensson, L. (1995): Inflation Targets. Center for Economic PolicyLondon.

Lutkepohl, H. (1993): Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Springer-VerlagBerlin.

Mishkin, F. (1984): The real interest rates: A multi-country empirical study. CanadianJournal of Economics 17, 283–311.

Mishkin, F. (1992): Is the Fisher effect for real? A re-examination of the relationshipbetween inflation and interest rates. Journal of Monetary Economics 30, 195–215.

Modigliani, F. and Sutch, R. (1966): Innovations in Interest Rate Policy. The AmericanEconomic Review 56(1/2), 4–17.

Plosser, C. and Rouwenhorst, K. (1994): International term structures and real economicgrowth. Journal of Monetary Economics 33(1/2), 133–155.

Rachev, S. and Mittnik, S. (2000): Stable Paretian Models in Finance. John Wiley &Sons Chichester.

Schich, S. (1999): The information content of the German term structure regardinginflation. Applied Financial Economics 9, 385–395.

69

Page 72: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

Schmidt, T. and Zimmermann, T. (2005): Effects of Oil Price Shocks on German Busi-ness Cycles. RWI Discussion Papers (31).

Sims, C. (1980): Macroeconomics and reality. Econometrica 48, 1–48.

Smith, K. (2002): Government bond markets, seasonality, diversification, and cointegra-tion: International evidence. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutionsand Money 25(2), 203–221.

Tsay, R. (2002): Analysis of Financial Time Series. John Wiley & Sons New York.

Turnovsky, S. (1989): The Term Structure of Interest Rates and the Effects of Macro-economic Policy. NBER Working Papers (2902).

Vasicek, O. (1977): An equilibrium characterisation of the term structure. Journal ofFinancial Economics 37, 339–348.

Verbeek, M. (2004): A Guide to Modern Econometrics. John Wiley & Sons New York.

Wang, Z., Yang, J., and Li, Q. (2004): International bond market linkages: a structuralVAR analysis. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money15(1), 39–54.

Weidmann, J. (1997): New Hope for the Fisher Effect? A Reexamination Using Thresh-old Cointegration. Institut fur Internationale Wirtschaftspolitik.

Yohe, W. and Karnosky, D. (1969): Interest Rates and Price Level Changes. FederalReserve Bank of St. Louis Review 51, 18–36.

Yuhn, K. (1996): Is the Fisher effect robust? Further evidence. Applied EconomicsLetters 3, 41–44.

70

Page 73: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

A Schwarz criterion

SIC = ln (σ) +2k

T(25)

where σ is the residual variance, k=p+q+1 is the total number of parameters estimatedand T is the sample size (Brooks, 2002).

B Akaike criterion

AIC = ln (σ) +k

Tln T (26)

where σ is the residual variance, k=p+q+1 is the total number of parameters estimatedand T is the sample size (Brooks, 2002).

C Adjusted R2

As the R2 never falls when additional regressors are added to the equation, the ad-justed R2 takes into account the loss of degrees of freedom associated with adding extravariables.

R2 = 1−(

T − 1

T − k(1−R2)

)(27)

where T is the number of observations and k the number of parameters in the model(Brooks, 2002).

D Log-likelihood function

The log-likelihood function is computed as follows and assumes normally distributederrors (Brooks, 2002).

l = −T

2(1 + log(2π) + log

(ε′ε

T

)) (28)

E Skewness

Skewness is a measure of asymmetry of the distribution of the series around its mean.Skewness is computed as:

S =1

N

N∑i=1

(yi − y

σ

)3

(29)

71

Page 74: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

The skewness of a symmetric distribution, such as the normal distribution, is zero.Positive skewness means that the distribution has a long right tail and negative skewnessimplies that the distribution has a long left tail (Brooks, 2002).

F Kurtosis

Kurtosis measures the peakedness or flatness of the distribution of the series. Kurtosisis computed as

K =1

N

N∑i=1

(yi − y

σ

)4

(30)

The kurtosis of the normal distribution is 3. If the kurtosis exceeds 3, the distribution ispeaked (leptokurtic) relative to the normal; if the kurtosis is less than 3, the distributionis flat (platykurtic) relative to the normal (Brooks, 2002).

G Jarque-Bera (JB) test of normality

The JB test of normality is an asymtotic, or large-sample, test. It is based on the OLSresiduals and uses the following test statistic:

JB = n

(S2

6+

(K − 3)2

24

)(31)

Under the null hypothesis, Jarque and Bera showed that asymptotically (i.e., in largesamples) the JB statistic in equation (31) follows the chi-square distribution with 2 df.

H Ito process

If a variable x follows an Ito process (Hull, 1999):

dx = a(x, t)dt + b(x, t)dz (32)

where dz is a Wiener process and a and b are functions of x and t. The variable x has adrift rate of a and a variance rate of b2. Ito’s lemma shows that a function, G, of x andt follows the process

dG =

(∂G

∂xa +

∂G

∂t+

1

2

∂2G

∂x2b2

)dt +

∂G

∂xbdz (33)

where the dz is the same Wiener process as in equation (33). Thus, G, also follows anIto process. It has drift rate of

72

Page 75: Empirical Analysis of the Relationship between the Yield

∂G

∂xa +

∂G

∂t+

1

2

∂2G

∂x2b2 (34)

and a variance rate of (∂G

∂x

)2

b2 (35)

73