Article - Pohl [255] - Final.pdfPolitical and Economic Factors
Influencing Strike Activity during the Recent Economic Crisis: A
Study of the Spanish
Case between 2002 and 20131
Nicholas Pohl, University of Lausanne, Switzerland ABSTRACT The
Great Recession and the upsurge of widespread social movements in
various crisis-ridden countries have given new impetus to the
debate on the relationship between economic breakdown and the
occurrence of collective action. I revisit the issue by examining
strike activity in Spain between 2002 and 2013. For a better
understanding of the continuities and changes, I contrast two sets
of literature on industrial conflict. The first deals with economic
factors influencing strikes or, in other words, with the question
of whether and how fluctuations in manpower supply and demand
account for continuities and changes in strike activity. The second
advocates for a look beyond the economy, towards the political
exchange that takes place between unions and state actors and
which, depending on its positive or negative nature, leads to
shifts of the distributional struggle away from the marketplace
towards the public arena or vice versa. The findings reveal that,
rather than exclusive, the two perspectives prove to be mutually
conducive and are most significant when they are combined. The
political exchange model is helpful for understanding the rather
stable or even declining strike frequency prior to the economic
crisis but also the three nationwide general strikes in 2010 and
2012, which represented a rupture in the social consensus. If the
general strikes are left aside, the economic variables come into
play: an increased strike frequency during the economic crisis is
in fact accompanied by a shift towards smaller strikes related to a
single workplace, and to so-called “defensive” strikes. This
indicates that an actual decrease in workers’ bargaining power was
overcompensated by a growing number of circumstances in which the
recourse to strike action became a means of last resort. KEY WORDS
strikes; economic cycles; political exchange; Great Recession;
Spain Introduction In the aftermath of the Great Recession
(2007–2012) more and more scholars began to dedicate their work to
people’s political responses to the negative consequences of the
economic crisis. An ever- growing literature in electoral research
trying to explain apparent shifts in voting behaviour (Bartels and
Bermeo, 2014; Hernández and Kriesi, 2016; Whiteley, 2016) is
accompanied by an increasing 1 A draft of this paper was presented
at the International Sociological Association’s RC48 PhD Workshop,
Vienna, 9 July 2016.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 20
number of publications on social movements, notably on the
“Indignados” in Spain and the “Occupy” movement in the United
States (Graeber, 2012; Della Porta and Mattoni, 2014; Ancelovici,
Dufour and Nez, 2016; Romanos, 2016; Della Porta et al., 2017).
Research on industrial conflict, too, has benefited from this
general upswing (Gallas, Nowak and Wilde, 2012; Nowak and Gallas,
2014; Gallas and Nowak, 2016). However, the literature on Spain
still reveals some weaknesses: either it is mainly descriptive (Gil
and Hernández, 2014; Lacalle, 2015) or it focuses primarily on
political aspects of strikes (Luque, 2012b), leaving aside economic
factors that are likely to affect strike activity in times of
economic crisis.
By conducting this research on the evolution of strike activity in
Spain between 2002 and 2013, I will contribute to filling this gap.
The economic factors will be analysed by measuring shifts in
manpower supply and demand which, according to the Business Cycle
Model (Rist, 1907; Rees, 1952; Skeels, 1971), lead to concomitant
shifts in workers’ bargaining power and thereby influence the
likelihood of strikes. Regarding the political aspects of strikes,
I will include the tripartite negotiations between unions,
employers and the state in order to examine whether strikes should
rather be considered as a consequence of a rupture in the positive
political exchange between unions and the state, in which the
government trades goods in exchange for social consensus (Pizzorno,
1978).
In order to examine the relevance of the Business Cycle Model, two
successive six-year periods in Spain’s recent history will be
compared – the first precedes the crisis (2002–2007) and the second
covers the first six years following the outbreak of the Great
Recession (2008–2013). Both periods are characterised by contrary
trends in employment data. This subdivision will enable me to
stress not only general trends or year-to-year changes but also to
compare the two periods en bloc.2. For the scrutiny of the
Political Exchange Model, the entire period under study will be
examined in terms of the changes in government and the evolution of
tripartite negotiations between the unions, the employers and the
state.
The article is structured as follows: In a first step, I present
different explanatory models for strikes, notably the Business
Cycle Model and the Political Exchange Model. Thereafter, I
explicate the notion of the shape of strikes (Shorter and Tilly,
1971, 1974) and its different aspects. The subsequent analysis
begins with a general exploration of the data at a national level
and is followed by an industry comparison. It is completed by
including strike motives and strike outcomes, which provide a
better understanding of how the crisis affected both the (offensive
or defensive) nature of strikes and the workers’ bargaining power.
Explaining Strike Activity Social sciences have proposed various –
in part contradictory – models for strike activity. In this section
I will discuss some of the main approaches and present the
perspective adopted in this article.
Historically, the first model to propose an explanation for strike
activity is the so-called Business Cycle Model (Rist, 1907). This
model acts on the assumption of a positive correlation between
economic boom and strike activity due to the fluctuations in
manpower supply and demand (Rist, 1907; Rees, 1952; Skeels, 1971).
In expansive economic periods, the need for manpower increases
while
2 Which would be more disputable if the adjacent years were taken
into account, since the unemployment rate increased by 0.8
percentage point between 2001 and 2002, and started to decrease
again from 2014 onwards.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 21
its supply decreases. Due to the difficulties of hiring new staff,
employers would thus try to avoid dismissals when facing strike
actions. The workers – knowing that even if they were to be
dismissed, they could rapidly take on a new job – are strengthened
in their bargaining position, which increases their propensity to
participate in strike action.
In opposition to the Business Cycle Model, economic hardship or
relative deprivation theories expect that “both short-term and
persistent deprivation are significant causes of the various forms
of civil strife” (Gurr, 1969: 603). These theories, which were
initially used for understanding the emergence of mobs, revolts or
revolutions, were later applied to industrial conflict in order to
explain heightened strike activity after periods of high inflation
(Jackson, Turner and Wilkinson, 1972; Soskice, 1978).
In a Marxist perspective, struggle is inherent in labour–capital
relations (Hyman, 1975). In this line, Silver (2003) asserts that
historical capitalism is based on two contradictory tendencies,
which lead to pendulum swings between “crises of profitability and
crises of social legitimacy” (Silver, 2003: 17). Thus, the
expansion of capitalist production would lead to a strengthening of
labour movements. With the objective of bringing labour under
control, capital (and states) would have to make concessions, which
provoke crises of profitability. In order to restore profits,
capital (and states) would then again have to break established
social conventions and intensify the commodification of labour,
thereby producing crises of social legitimacy and backlash
resistances. In this perspective, crises of profitability are
provoked by so-called “Marx-type labour unrest” – that is,
offensive struggles led by the emerging working class. On the
opposite side, crises of social legitimacy lead to “Polanyi-type
labour unrest” – that is, backlash resistances to the continuous
spread of self-regulating markets, in particular by the workers
most affected by the disbanding of social contracts or by global
economic transformations (Silver, 2003: 20).
Proponents of the institutionalisation approach argue that more
attention should be paid to the institutional context and to the
continuing regulation and thus institutionalisation of unions and
their means of action (Adam and Reynaud, 1978). In this
perspective, unions would increasingly opt for institutional
channels – which are considered more efficient and less costly than
strike actions – in order to reach agreements with employers
(Tixier, 2007).
Closer to political science, researchers stressed the importance of
considering the political context and the resulting political
exchange between governments and unions (Hibbs, 1978; Pizzorno,
1978). In this model, strike activity is explained by the power of
unions in the political sphere. In countries where bonds between
government and unions are strong, unions are expected to avoid the
costs of strike action and to intervene in the political sphere,
where they have good chances to attain their goals. In contrast, in
countries where these bonds are weak or absent, unions have to
exert pressure by the means of collective action (Korpi and Shalev,
1979). The Political Exchange Model not only allows for
cross-country analyses but also for single case studies, where the
focus is put on shifts of power between different political parties
(on the Spanish case, see Luque, 2012a, 2012b, 2013). The political
exchange can be considered as “positive” if bonds between unions
and the government are strong and an ongoing social dialogue
prevails. It turns “negative” when the dialogue comes to a halt or
does not exist and the unions adopt contentious tactics to exert
pressure on the state (Luque, 2012b: 99).
Because of the limited time period under study, I will not be able
to put all the models to the test. Institutionalisation, for
instance, is considered an ongoing but in particular a long-run
process. For its examination, it would be necessary to include the
entire process since Spain’s so-called transition
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 22
to democracy in the second half of the 1970s. The same accounts for
the scrutiny of Silver’s (2003) model of the pendulum swings
between crises of profitability and crises of social legitimacy.
Her model better suits mid- or long-term processes and does not
apply to the 2008 financial crisis, which was not a “crisis of
profitability” caused by concessions made by employers in order to
bring labour movements under control.
The above-mentioned restrictions led me to focus this analysis on
two dimensions of strikes and on their related explanatory models:
first, the political dimension and the corresponding political
exchange model, which expects heightened strike activity after the
imposition of labour market reforms by the Spanish government
against the will of the unions; and second, the economic dimension,
where I will address the question of whether the economic crisis
has weakened the workers’ bargaining power and thus led to a
decrease in strike activity (which would be in line with the
Business Cycle Model) or, on the contrary, whether the relative
deprivation produced by the economic crisis has fomented the use of
strikes (which would be in line with the relative deprivation
hypothesis).
Conceptualisation of Strike Activity Following the definition of
the International Labour Organization (ILO, 1993: n.p.), strikes
are considered here as “a temporary work stoppage effected by one
or more groups of workers with a view to enforcing or resisting
demands or expressing grievances, or supporting other workers in
their demands or grievances”. The investigation of strike activity
will be based on annual data provided by the Spanish Ministry of
Employment and Social Security. It collects statistics on the
number of strikes, the number of workers participating in strike
action and the number of working days lost due to strike action,
and breaks these variables down according to different
subcategories (e.g. economic sector, strike motives, strike
outcome). Not included in the data provided by this ministry are
values regarding one nationwide strike of the public sector in 2010
and three nationwide general strikes3 (one in 2010 and two in
2012). Following the approach adopted by González and Luque (2014)
and Luque and González (2016), the missing data regarding the three
nationwide general strikes will be reconstructed on the basis of
surveys conducted by the Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas in
the aftermath of each general strike. Extrapolating these numbers
to the entire working population allows for rough estimates
regarding participation in the general strikes. As a result, only
the 2010 strike of the public sector, for which the same survey
procedure does not apply, has to be omitted from the
analysis.
In this paper, I will go beyond an evaluation of the absolute
numbers provided by the Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social
Security and include an analysis of the shape of strikes, as
proposed by Shorter and Tilly (1971; 1974) and later adopted by
various other scholars (Hibbs, 1978; Luque, Cueto and Mato, 2008;
Luque, 2013). According to this conceptualisation, various aspects
of strike activity should be considered: first, the size of
strikes, defined as the total number of strikers over the total
number of strikes; second, their duration, specified as working
days lost in strike action over the number of workers involved; and
third, the strike frequency, calculated by the total number of
strikes over the working population under study. Based on these
three aspects of strikes, two additional
3 Although three general strikes occurred during the economic
crisis, the Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security
provides data only on the first general strike of the period under
study, which took place in 2002.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 23
characteristics of strikes can be defined: strike magnitude, which
is equal to the average of working days lost per strike; and strike
volume, which is equal to the working days lost per 1 000
employees.
Strike volume = strike size x strike duration x strike
frequency
1 000 = ( )
This conceptualisation has the advantage of making visible various
aspects of strikes, which the absolute numbers do not reflect. The
identical magnitude or volume of strike activity can in fact differ
significantly in their shapes. For instance, as shown in Figure 1,
large strike size combined with low strike duration can produce the
same strike magnitude (or strike volume) as small strikes of long
duration.
Figure 1. Possible different shapes of the same strike volume
This definition leads us to discuss the possible implications of
the two theoretical models under study on the shape of strikes
during the recent economic crisis in Spain. Strike frequency would
be expected to decrease in the Business Cycle Model, whereas in the
Political Exchange Model an increase is, if not expected, then at
least conceivable after the social consensus has come to an end.
Regarding the strike duration, the Business Cycle Model suggests
two contrary scenarios: On the one hand, workers are expected to
aim at reducing additional money loss which strike action involves
and thus to limit strike duration. On the other hand, due to their
increased bargaining power, employers are expected to be less
likely to comply with workers’ claims, which would cause workers to
strike for longer periods in order to have their demands met. The
Political Exchange Model is not explicit regarding strike duration.
Having said this, it stresses the demonstrative aspect of strikes:
they are directed toward the government rather than intended to
inflict losses in production on the employers. This suggests that
strikes do not have to be particularly long. Regarding strike size,
the Business Cycle Model would indicate a decline due to a shift
from more general (offensive) demands, such as claims for
collective agreements for entire industries, towards more
factory-related strikes against specific threats such as factory
closures or mass dismissals. In the Political Exchange Model,
strike size is crucial for exerting pressure on the government and
is thus expected to rise after a disbanding of the social
consensus. The following section will put these different
hypotheses to the test.
a a
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 24
Political and Economic Aspects of Strike Activity during the Recent
Economic Crisis in Spain The state of the economy and political
transformations between 2002 and 2013 In this section, I will first
present the economic performance of the country by taking a closer
look at employment levels in general but also at the different
economic sectors. In a second step, I will portray some of the most
relevant political transformations which are likely to have
affected workers and unions. This will help to examine, in the
later sub-sections, which factors actually account for continuities
and changes in strike activity during the recent economic
crisis.
As it is shown in Table 1, the first six-year period presents a
decrease in unemployment rates4 and a relatively steady increase in
the total number of persons employed. In the second period, this
trend is reversed, still slight in 2008 and sharply in 2009. The
specification of employment levels for different economic sectors
shows that they were unequally affected by the economic crisis. The
number of persons employed in the service sector continued to
increase in 2008 and experienced a comparatively moderate decrease
during subsequent years. In the industrial sector, employment
remained virtually stable until 2008 but suffered a sudden drop in
2009 and continued to decrease until 2013, losing 28 per cent of
its workforce between 2007 and 2013. Of all sectors, the
construction sector experienced the strongest increase in
employment levels in the run-up to the crisis, but, after the
bursting of the real estate bubble, it also underwent the sharpest
decline, losing more than 60 per cent of its workforce between 2007
and 2013 and remaining, in 2013, at 52 per cent of the employment
level of 2002. The agricultural sector shows a particular evolution
with relatively stable numbers between 2002 and 2005, but losing 7
per cent of its workforce during the subsequent two years and thus
prior to the outbreak of the crisis. The number of persons employed
in the agricultural sector further decreased during the crisis,
reaching, in 2013, 78 per cent of the employment level recorded in
2002. A divergence also becomes manifest when comparing the private
with the public sector. While in the former sector employment
levels started to decrease in 2008 and, by 2013, were virtually
equal to the level of 2002, the latter sector further expanded
until 2011 and only decreased during the last two years under
study.
The numbers thus indicate that although a trend reversal can
already be discerned in 2008, employment was particularly struck in
2009 and then continued to decrease in successive years. The only
exceptions to this were in the agricultural sector, which was
already experiencing a decline prior to the crisis, and the public
sector, which seems to have been more resistant to the negative
consequences of the economic crisis, at least until 2012.
4 The year 2003 is the only year to present a slight deviation,
with an increase of 0.1 percentage point in the unemployment
rate.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 25
Table 1. Unemployment rates, total employment and employment in
different sectors
Notes: (1) Per cent values show the relative changes compared to
the base year, 2002. (2) Employment numbers are in thousands and
include self-employed people. As the latter implies that the number
of employed people susceptible to participate in strike action is
in fact lower, the calculated rates of strike frequency (and thus
also of strike volumes) have to be considered underestimations.
Sources: labour statistics from Eurostat (n.d.), ILO (n.d.) and
OECD (n.d.).
At a political level, the timeframe under study begins with the two
last years of the conservative Popular Party’s (PP) government led
by José María Aznar, whose “third way conservatism” (Hamann, 2005),
characterised by tripartite negotiations, came to a momentary halt
when he implemented a reform of the unemployment benefit system
despite the opposition of the two major unions Comisiones Obreras
(CCOO) and Unión General de Trabajadores (UGT). In 2004, the
Spanish Socialist Workers’ Party (PSOE) wan the parliamentary
elections and José Luis Rodriguéz Zapatero was elected Prime
Minister of Spain. This led to a strengthening of the social
dialogue between unions, employers and the state. Yet, the economic
crisis and the concomitant credit restrictions in the private
sector and the steep rise in unemployment led to a severe fiscal
crisis. In 2010, the social democratic government considered that
cuts in public spending were unavoidable to remedy the country’s
budget crisis, and in May of that same year the government decreed
the first austerity measures, including a 5 per cent wage cut in
the public sector. Shortly after, in June 2010, the government
finally unilaterally decreed a labour market reform. This
unilateral path did not last long. During the following year,
tripartite negotiations were resumed and a “social and economic
agreement” was reached, which should favour growth, job creation
and guarantee pensions. That same year, Zapatero called early
elections, which were won by the Popular Party under the leadership
of Mariano Rajoy. This government pushed another labour market
reform, which was decreed in February 2012 against the will of CCOO
and UGT.
The overview: a descriptive account of strike activity prior to and
during the recent economic crisis in Spain Before trying to
understand why some aspects of strikes changed after the outbreak
of the Great Recession, I will draw a picture of how they have
changed, notably by comparing the six-year period
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 26
preceding the Great Recession (2002–2007) and the one covering the
first six years since its outbreak (2008–2013).
As is clear from Table 2, different aspects of strikes have evolved
unequally over time. Furthermore, certain aspects of strikes –
notably strike size – vary greatly depending on whether or not
general strikes are taken into account. In order to facilitate the
subsequent interpretation, I will first depict the evolution of the
shape of strikes by omitting the general strikes and then show how
the picture changes when they are included. Table 2. Strike
activity in Spain between 2002 and 2013
Notes: (1) Values in brackets include general strikes. (2) Due to
lack of data, the values do not include the general strike of the
public sector which took place on 8 June 2010. (3) Numbers of
participants in the 2010 and 2012 general strikes are taken from
Luque and González (2016: 12). Source: Spanish Ministry of
Employment and Social Security (n.d.) (unless otherwise specified);
own calculations.
Regarding the mean strike frequency, the value for the second
period under study is 29 per cent
(or 1.1 percentage point) higher than the one recorded for the
pre-crisis period. Contemplating only the absolute numbers of
strikes, one would be tempted to infer that an increase in strike
activity already occurred prior to the crisis, since 2006 and 2007
show the highest values of the first six-year period. The
measurement of strike frequency (and thus the consideration of the
growing employment levels during the first six years under study),
however, shows that strike frequency remained rather stable (or
even decreased) during this first period and that it experienced a
first sharp increase only in 2009 (see
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 27
Figure 2). The data also reveal a dip in 2011 before reaching the
highest score in 2013, overtopping (in strike frequency but not in
absolute values) the level of 2009.
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.);
own calculations.
Figure 2. Number of strikes and strike frequency in Spain
Regarding strike size, a trend towards smaller strikes can be
observed. The first six-year period
is characterised by relatively high strike size levels (978 workers
per strike in 2002 and 1 081 workers per strike in 2003); this more
than halves by 2005, reaching only 495 per strike in that year.
During the following four years the level settles at around 650,
but then drops again in 2010, reaching the lowest level in 2011
(286 workers per strike). During the two subsequent years the level
slightly increases again, but remains under the level observed at
the onset of the crisis.
For the period of the economic crisis, the mean strike duration has
fallen slightly (from 2.9 days per strike to 2.6) compared to the
prior period. However, this finding is mainly due to an outlier
case in 2004, when the average strike duration reached 8 days per
striker. This value – twice as high as the second highest number
(reached in 2012) – results from an extraordinarily long-lasting
strike in the agricultural sector in Andalusia. If we leave aside
this outlier, the conclusion would in fact be reversed and the
crisis would have been accompanied by an increase in strike
duration. Since strike duration is a multiplication factor in both
strike magnitude and strike volume, this outlier case also becomes
visible in these respective values. While the mean strike magnitude
between 2002 and 2007 remains above the one calculated for the
second period, even when the outlier is left aside, the same does
not apply to the strike volume, where a slight increase can be
observed during the crisis if the outlier case is not included. The
fact that, when omitting the outlier, the increase in strike volume
is accompanied by a decrease in strike magnitude indicates that the
increase in strike duration did not outweigh the decrease in strike
size (since strike magnitude still decreases) and, hence, that the
increase in strike volume is
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 28
mainly due to the increased strike frequency. Regarding the course
of their evolution, strike magnitude and strike volume (including
the outlier
case) show a similar evolution. Both reflect the outlier peak in
2004, an upwards trend between 2005 and 2008, a subsequent dip
after the onset of the crisis, and again higher values for the last
two years under study (see Figure 3).
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security; own
calculations.
Figure 3. Strike magnitude and strike volume The aspects most
affected by the inclusion of the four general strikes (in 2002,
2010, and two in
2012) are strike size and, to a lesser extent, strike duration. Not
surprisingly, the mean strike size significantly increases. The
fact that three out of four general strikes occurred during the
second period under study also inverts the above-described tendency
towards smaller strikes (with 2 043 workers per strike for the
latter period compared to 1 713 for the prior period). Strike
duration decreases since all general strikes lasted only one day
(i.e. less than the average strike duration when omitting general
strikes). Here again, the effect is greater in the second period
where three general strikes occurred and the drop in strike
duration is more substantial (from 2.8 days per strike during the
first period to 1.9 during the second) than if general strikes are
omitted (from 2.9 to 2.6 days per strike).
As a consequence of the above described changes in strike size and
strike duration, strike magnitude and strike volume also increase
and, by including three new peak years (2012, 2002 and to a lesser
extent 2010), depict more accurately the actual dimensions of
strike magnitudes and strike volumes between 2002 and 2013 (see
Figure 3). Compared to the numbers omitting general strikes, mean
strike magnitude increases by 76 per cent (reaching 2 928 working
days lost per strike compared to 1 667 when omitting the general
strikes). Furthermore, the gap between the periods under study
becomes smaller (with 3 103 working days lost per strike during the
first period and 2 752 during the second) and is actually reversed
if the outlier case in 2004 is left aside. Regarding strike volume,
the mean of the second period (137 working days lost per 1 000
employees) exceeds the pre-crisis period (122 working days lost per
1 000 employees) even when the 2004 outlier case is included. This
points to the impact of the increase in strike size during the
second period, which is mainly due to the two general strikes in
2012.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 29
First insights: lack of alignment between the theoretical models
and the observed strike activity The picture presented above
provides strong arguments against the Business Cycle Model.
Contrary to the expected downward trend in strike activity, strike
frequency significantly increased during the economic crisis. The
other aspects of strikes do not show as clear-cut trends. However,
if the general strikes are taken into account, both strike size and
strike volume also increase, which also goes against the
expectations of the model. When looking at the general picture,
economic factors as specified in the Business Cycle Model do not
seem to account for the observed strike activity during the recent
economic crisis. One could even argue that the findings are rather
in line with the theoretical counterpart – the relative deprivation
hypothesis – which considers that “both short-term and persistent
deprivation are significant causes of the various forms of civil
strife” (Gurr, 1969: 603).
Compared with the Business Cycle Model, the Political Exchange
Model seems to fit much better. The timeframe under study begins
with a general strike in 2002, which represents a rupture in the
“third way conservatism” (Hamann, 2005), leading to a negative turn
in the political exchange between the conservative government and
the unions. A period of enhanced social dialogue follows the coming
into power of the social democratic party in 2004 – that is, a
period of positive political exchange – which is reflected in
rather low and stable strike frequency. Yet, the Great Recession
changes the parameters of the social dialogue, and in 2010 the
social democratic government is forced to implement cuts in public
spending as well as labour market reform. These announcements are
followed, in the same year, first by a general strike in the public
sector and soon after by a cross-sectoral general strike. The year
after, tripartite negotiations are resumed, which is accompanied by
an important dip in strike magnitude and strike volume.
Furthermore, these lowest levels of strike magnitude and strike
volume reached in 2011 also coincide with national elections, which
could indicate that the unions intentionally tempered their use of
contentious tactics in support of the social democratic president
seeking re-election. If general strikes are included, the highest
values of strike volume are measured for 2012, the year in which
the newly elected conservative government decrees labour market
reform going far beyond the one implemented by the social
democratic government two years earlier. As a reaction, and for the
first time since the so-called transition to democracy, two
nationwide general strikes are called during a single year. The
political exchange having clearly turned negative again, it remains
negative also in 2013, when the highest values of strike frequency
can be observed.
While the Political Exchange Model is able to account for periods
of relatively stable strike activity but also for sudden massive
strikes, there are also evolutions which are more difficult to
explain. For instance, how should one interpret the steep increase
in strike frequency in 2009, which happened prior to the rupture in
the positive political exchange between unions and the social
democratic government? And what about the tendency towards smaller
strikes (if general strikes are not included)? If strikes are
directed towards the government, why should strikes become smaller
in size? Since neither of the two models have yielded satisfactory
explanations for the general evolutions in the shape of strikes, I
will further disentangle the issue by comparing the shape of
strikes among different economic sectors.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 30
Similarities and disparities between different economic sectors A
comparison of the shape of strikes in different economic sectors
exhibits differences independent of the economic crisis. In line
with other studies on industrial action (see Salamon, 2000), the
industrial sector exhibits by far the highest strike frequency for
the whole period under study (see Figure 4). In addition, a sharp
increase in strike frequency can be observed since the outbreak of
the crisis. The second highest values (but at a considerably lower
level) are reached by the service sector. These values show a
slight downward trend prior to the crisis and a slight upward trend
during the crisis. The construction sector has experienced the
sharpest increase in strike frequency in the aftermath of the
crisis. While there was a mean strike frequency of 0.54 per 100 000
workers for the period between 2002 and 2007, this value more than
quintupled in the second period under study (2.87 strikes per 100
000 workers) and has, at times, even equalled the strike frequency
of the service sector. In the case of the construction sector, the
sharp increase in strike frequency is the combined result of an
increase in the absolute number of strikes and the aforementioned
sharp decrease in employment levels. The agricultural sector
exhibits an unsteady evolution at a rather low level, showing the
lowest rates of strike activity of the four sectors in 2006 and
2007 and again from 2009 onwards.
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.);
own calculations.
Figure 4. Strike frequency in various economic sectors
Overall, the mean strike size decreased between the two periods
under study in three out of four sectors (industry, construction
and services; see Table 3) – rather slightly (by 7.1 per cent) in
the service sector, more substantially in the industrial sector (by
25.8 per cent), and the most in the construction sector (by 58.7
per cent). The agricultural sector is the only one to exhibit an
increase in the mean strike size (by 20.5 per cent, and even more
than twelve-fold if we leave aside the outlier case in 2004).
Similarly to the general figures, strike duration also exhibits an
unsteady course when subdivided into economic sectors. The only
sector with a relatively constant strike duration level is the
service sector. Seen over the whole period of observation it varies
between 1.4 and 3.8 days per striker, and
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 31
the mean values of both periods are identical (2.4 days per
striker). The construction and the agricultural sector exhibit
higher peaks prior to the crisis (even when excluding the outlier
case). This explains why the mean values of the first six-year
period are higher than the ones of the second period.5 The
industrial sector is the only one to manifest an increase in mean
strike duration (from 2.7 to 3.7 days per striker), which is mainly
due to a peak in 2012, where it reached 8.9 days per striker.
Table 3. Strike size and strike duration according to economic
sector
Notes: (1) Values include the public sector (mainly as part of the
service sector) but neither the four nationwide general strikes in
2002, 2010 and 2012 nor the nationwide general strike of the public
sector in 2010. (2) Values in brackets exclude an outlier case in
2004. Sources: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security
(n.d.); own calculations. Articulation of strike frequency with the
respective employment levels in the different sectors
indicates that those sectors which experienced the most sudden and
the sharpest decrease in employment (i.e. construction and
industry) were also those that have seen their strike frequency
increase most abruptly. The findings thus suggest that the deeper
and the more sudden negative impacts of the economic crisis are,
the more frequently workers resort to strikes. Diametrically
opposed to the Business Cycle Model, this seems again rather in
line with its counterpart, the relative deprivation hypothesis.
However, before jumping to premature conclusions, I will further
deepen the analysis by comparing the evolutions between the public
and the private sectors.
5 It is noteworthy to mention that in the construction sector the
highest value of strike size during the crisis period (recorded at
its outbreak in 2008) coincides with the lowest value of strike
duration (0.03 days per striker, which is equal to 43 minutes per
striker). This finding calls for further examination but could be
an indicator that the workers in this sector were taken by surprise
and that they were overstrained with the events.
Year Industry Construction Services Industry Construction Services
2002 194 253 53 521 4.1 3.4 28.2 2.1 2003 220 443 69 266 2.9 3.0
16.0 2.6 2004 8380 (256) 583 1356 639 27.4 (7.7) 2.6 26.1 1.9 2005
113 608 67 419 12.7 1.7 2.0 2.9 2006 35 422 6374 501 3.8 2.3 1.0
2.1 2007 64 272 5645 513 7.7 2.9 3.6 2.5
Mean (2002-2007) 1501 (147) 430 2261 477 9.8 (6.5) 2.7 12.8 2.4
2008 644 454 3026 665 3.0 2.5 0.0 3.8 2009 6058 598 2032 324 4.0
1.8 1.1 1.9 2010 3321 231 105 358 1.0 3.1 9.7 1.4 2011 135 201 249
279 2.0 2.6 1.8 2.4 2012 39 211 60 393 1.7 8.9 5.9 2.9 2013 656 220
133 641 2.5 3.1 11.6 2.2
Mean (2008-2013) 1809 319 934 443 2.4 3.7 5.0 2.4 Mean (2002-2013)
1655 (978) 375 1597 460 6.1 (4.4) 3.2 8.9 2.4
Strike duration Agriculture
Strike size Agriculture
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 32
Some contrary trends in the public and the private sectors The
shape of strikes exhibits some clear differences between public and
private ownership of the workplaces. For nearly the entire period
under study, strike duration has been higher and strike size lower
in the private sector (see Table 4). I expect the difference in
strike size to be due to the fact that different activities in the
public sector are eventually united under one common negotiating
partner (at local, regional or national level), which facilitates
inter-professional and thus bigger strikes. Regarding strike
duration, the data suggests that negotiations are tougher in the
private sector, which requires longer strike actions from the
workers in this sector. Table 4. Strike activity in the private and
public sectors
Notes: (1) Values include neither the four nationwide general
strikes in 2002, 2010 and 2012 nor the nationwide general strike of
the public sector in 2010. (2) Values in brackets exclude an
outlier case in 2004 Sources: Spanish Ministry of Employment and
Social Security (n.d); own calculations.
When comparing strike frequency between the private and the public
sectors, two contrary
trends can be discerned (see Figure 5). Although with a high
volatility, a tendency towards a decline in strike frequency can be
observed in the public sector. In the private sector, the slight
downward trend observed prior to the crisis has inverted sharply
with the outbreak of the crisis. Both tendencies combined have led,
at the outset of the crisis, to an inversion of the sector more
prone to engage in strike action. This leads us to the conclusion
that the increase in strike frequency presented in the previous
subsections has to be ascribed entirely to the private
sector.
The relative stability in the workforce in the public sector (and
its increase until 2011) indicates that this sector has been less
affected by the economic crisis, and at a later point. In the
private sector, where an important decrease in employment levels
can be observed for the period following the outbreak of the
economic crisis, the increase in strike frequency would again be in
line with the relative deprivation hypothesis. However, as I will
show in the following sections, it would be misleading to ascribe
the increase in strike frequency in the private sector to an
increased strike propensity in this sector.
Public sector Public sector Public sector Public sector Public
sector
2002 3.82 5.02 308 755 2.9 2.0 895 1473 34 74 2003 3.72 4.36 355
4491 3.2 0.3 1139 1345 42 59 2004 3.45 (3.44) 5.96 696 (482) 877
11.2 (3.6) 1.5 7768 (1737) 1353 268 (60) 81 2005 3.15 4.99 384 656
2.3 2.8 874 1859 28 93 2006 3.61 4.96 362 653 2.2 2.2 796 1444 29
72 2007 3.46 4.33 416 532 3.2 2.6 1345 1398 47 60
Mean 2002-2007 3.53 (3.53) 4.94 420 (385) 1327 4.2 (2.9) 1.9 2136
(1131) 1479 75 (40) 73 2008 3.67 5.21 462 883 3.6 2.8 1667 2466 61
128 2009 5.62 3.14 606 934 2.1 1.1 1299 1070 73 34 2010 5.35 4.35
247 902 2.6 1.0 650 863 35 37 2011 4.52 2.57 164 891 2.7 2.0 440
1767 20 45 2012 5.06 3.98 143 1111 7.8 2.6 1123 2928 57 117 2013
6.20 3.51 305 528 3.0 2.2 917 1174 57 41
Mean 2008-2013 5.07 3.79 321 875 3.6 2.0 1016 1711 50 67 Mean
2002-2013 4.30 (4.30) 4.36 371 (353) 1101 3.9 (3.3) 1.9 1576 (1073)
1595 62 (45) 70
Private sector Year
Private sector Private sector Private sector Private sector Strike
frequency Strike size Strike duration Strike magmitude Strike
volume
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 33
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.);
own calculations.
Figure 5. Strike frequency according to the private and the public
sector
A shift towards single-workplace-related and more defensive strikes
The increase in strike frequency combined with the decline in
strike size (if general strikes are omitted) invites one to examine
the background of this trend. As illustrated in Figure 6, the
numbers indicate that the increase in strike actions is primarily
due to an increased strike frequency in single workplaces. This
points to a shift away from more general (e.g. sectoral or
industry-wide) strikes towards strikes related to single
workplaces.
This again raises the question of the background of this increase
in single-workplace-related strikes. The examination of strike
motives provides some explanations. As shown in Figure 7, the
frequency of collective-bargaining-related strikes decreased while
the frequency of other labour- related strikes increased and
frequency of non-labour-related strikes (such as union-related
strikes, solidarity strikes, or strikes against policy reforms)
remained rather stable.
When analysing the motives of labour-related (but not
collective-bargaining-related) strikes, a shift towards strikes
that can be considered more defensive becomes evident. For example,
non- payment of wages as a strike motive experienced a sharp
increase between 2009 and 2010 and has become the most frequent
motive for strikes ever since. Strikes due to industrial
restructuring or staff downsizing plans have also increased
strongly in 2009 but the subsequent evolution of their frequency
has been more volatile. The frequency of strikes due to
disciplinary measures of the company (including dismissals of
single workers) or because of non-compliance with labour and
employment laws have also increased, although to a lesser
extent.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 34
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d);
own calculations.
Figure 6. Strike frequency according to number of implicated
workplaces
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.);
own calculations.
Figure 7. Strike frequency according to strike motives
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 35
This increase in strike motives which can be qualified as
“defensive” due to their objective of preventing or undoing layoffs
or deterioration of working conditions was accompanied by a
decrease in “offensive” strike motives – that is, strikes seeking
an improvement of working conditions and thus going beyond the
preservation of the status quo. When omitting collective bargaining
– which can but does not necessarily include aims for improvements
– the data provides two motives which can be assigned to those
“offensive” motives: “improvements independent from collective
agreements” or “improvements for staffs not covered by collective
agreements”. The first motive shows a decrease for the period
following the outbreak of the crisis, reaching its lowest level
during the last two years under study. The second motive exposes a
similar tendency but completely ceases to occur during the last two
years under study. Finally, other strike motives include the
following categories: workflow-related strikes, strikes due to
labour-related accidents, and “other” strike motives. These cannot
be clearly ascribed to either offensive or defensive categories,
and equally expose a declining trend. When added up into three
categories (defensive strike motives, offensive strike motives,
other strike motives), the increase in defensive strike motives
becomes even more apparent, as is clear in Figure 8.
Source: Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.);
own calculations.
Figure 8. Strike frequency (labour-related motives excluding
collective bargaining) according to the offensive or defensive
nature of strike motives
The increased frequency of defensive strikes is in line with the
previous observations of an increase in single-workplace-related
strikes. Staff downsizing, industrial restructuring and non-
payment of wages – to mention only the most frequent strike motives
– may be widespread in times of crisis but they manifest themselves
primarily at company or workplace level. All this indicates that,
after all, the underlying assumption of the Business Cycle Model –
that is, a decrease in workers’ bargaining power in times of
economic downturn – indeed applies to the Spanish case. However,
the
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 36
decreasing propensity of the workers to go on strike was
overcompensated by an increasing number of circumstances in which
defensive strike actions became a means of last resort. Conclusion
This article has aimed to provide a better understanding of the
evolution of strike activity in Spain between 2002 and 2013. The
presented analysis is based on a descriptive evaluation of data
provided by the Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security,
which served as a basis in order to calculate variables able to
reflect the “shape of strikes” (Shorter and Tilly, 1974). This made
possible an analysis of different aspects of strikes, which would
not have become visible through the examination of the absolute
numbers provided by the Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social
Security.
As shown in the descriptive part of the paper, the crisis was
accompanied by a manifest increase in strike frequency and by three
nationwide general strikes in 2010 and 2012. However, if the
general strikes are excluded, the crisis is accompanied by a (less
distinct) decrease in strike size after 2009. The sectoral analysis
equally presents an increase in mean strike frequency with the
outbreak of the economic crisis in all four economic sectors
(agriculture, industry, construction and services). The fact that
the sharpest increases in strike frequency were recorded in the
sectors most hit by the economic crisis (i.e. construction and
industry) suggests a positive correlation between the intensity of
job destruction and strike frequency. This hypothesis is supported
by a similar but much weaker tendency observed in the service
sector, where the decrease in employment levels was considerably
lower. Regarding strike size, a similar pattern could be discerned
for these three sectors: all show a decrease in strike size during
the second period under study, more pronounced in the construction
and in the industrial sectors and less so in the service sector.
This suggests that the increased number of mass layoffs,
non-payment of wages and other deterioration of working conditions
provided an increased number of motives for strikes, although on a
smaller scale. This finding is supported by the identified increase
in strikes in single workplaces. Whereas employment levels
negatively correlate with strike frequency and strike size in the
three above-mentioned sectors, other variables are needed in order
to explain the evolution in the agricultural sector, where no
particular crisis-related pattern could be observed.
As the shift towards single-workplace-related strikes already
indicates, it would be erroneous to conclude that the increased
strike frequency results from an increased propensity for strike
action. In fact, the inversion that occurred between the private
and public sectors regarding their respective strike frequency
suggests rather the opposite: in the public sector where, during
the timeframe under study, the impact of the economic crisis has
been considerably weaker than in the private sector, a decreasing
strike frequency could be observed. It can be assumed that the
economic crisis caused uncertainty among the workers in the public
sector, which led them to moderate their claims. The opposite trend
was observed in the private sector; rather than accounting for an
increasing propensity to go on strikes, this suggests that an
actual decrease in workers’ bargaining power was overcompensated by
a growing number of cases in which the recourse to strike action
appeared as a means of last resort (e.g. mass layoffs or
non-payment of wages).
The analysis presented here shows that, alone, neither the Business
Cycle Model nor the Political Exchange Model is able to account for
the evolution in strike activity between 2002 and 2013 in
Spain.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 37
As became clear, the Political Exchange Model proves to be useful
for understanding rather stable periods such as the one preceding
the economic crisis, the peaks (i.e. the occurrence of large-scale,
nationwide general strikes), but also of dips, such as the one
observed in both strike frequency and strike volume in 2011. It
seems probable that the unions indeed limited their strikes to the
minimum in order to relieve pressure on the social democratic party
in power, whose prime minister was running for re-election. Yet,
that same model proves less suitable for explaining the evolutions
at a smaller scale. The Business Cycle Model, for its part, is
unable to explain the peaks (i.e. the general strikes) but also
sudden dips. What’s more, the increased strike frequency during the
crisis manifestly contradicts the model, which expects periods of
economic downturn to weaken workers’ bargaining power and thus to
lead a decreasing number of strikes. However, while my work
contradicts the expected result of the model, the shift towards
single-workplace-related and so-called “defensive” strikes strongly
suggests that the shape but also the character of strikes were much
affected by the weakened bargaining position of the workers.
The usefulness of combining the two theoretical models points at
the weaknesses of previous works on the Spanish case, which are
mainly descriptive (Gil and Hernández, 2014; Lacalle, 2015;) or
focus primarily on political aspects of strikes (Luque, 2012b),
thereby underestimating economic factors which have proven to
affect strike activity in times of economic crisis. Yet, the
analysis also has its weaknesses. First, the dichotomic division
into a period preceding the crisis (2002–2007) and another
beginning at its outbreak (2008–2013) might be oversimplified and
would need more specification. A more precise image of the
evolution of the crisis would surely facilitate a better
understanding of the relationship between the course of the crisis
and strike activity. Likewise, state interventions, policy changes
or their respective announcement (Edelman, 1985) should be given
greater attention, since particularly (announcements of) policy
changes affecting the bargaining framework are likely to affect
strike activity. Second, other theoretical approaches (e.g.
Marxist, institutional theories, or the resource mobilisation
approach) might have provided further pieces of the “puzzle of
strikes” (Franzosi, 1995).
Finally, an argument should be made for adopting a broader
perspective on industrial conflict. Relating strikes to other forms
of resistance (e.g. demonstrations, petitions, sit-ins, etc.) would
provide a better understanding of the interconnectedness of these
different political phenomena. In fact, recent research indicates
that scholars working on industrial conflict would be well advised
to enlarge their scope to forms of resistance other than strikes
(Béroud et al., 2008; Groux and Pernot, 2008; Giraud, 2009). These
scholars have found that industrial conflict can actually increase
even in periods of declining strike activity, when tactics other
than strikes are taken into account. While posing many
methodological challenges, such perspective would take us a good
way towards a more complex consideration of social contention –
notably in times of economic crisis.
REFERENCES
Adam, G. and J.-D. Reynaud (1978) Conflits du travail et changement
social. Paris: PUF.
Ancelovici, M., P. Dufour and H. Nez (eds.) (2016) Street Politics
in the Age of Austerity: From the Indignados to Occupy. Amsterdam:
Amsterdam University Press.
Bartels, L. and N. Bermeo (eds.) (2014) Mass Politics in Tough
Times: Opinions, Votes and Protest in the Great Recession. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 38
Béroud, S., J.-M. Denis, G. Desage, B. Giraud and J. Pélisse (2008)
La lutte continue? Les conflits du travail dans la France
contemporaine. Bellecombe-en-Bauges: Éditions le Croquant.
Della Porta, D., M. Andretta, T. Fernandes, E. Romanos, F.P.
O’Connor and M. Vogiatzoglou (2017) Late Neoliberalism and its
Discontents in the Economic Crisis: Comparing Social Movements in
the European Periphery. Cham: Springer.
Della Porta, D. and A. Mattoni (2014) Spreading Protest: Social
Movements in Times of Crisis. Colchester: ECPR Press.
Edelman, M. (1985) The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Champaign:
University of Illinois Press.
Eurostat (n.d.) Labour Force Survey. Available at
http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/lfs/data/database [accessed 16
January 2017].
Franzosi, R. (1995) The Puzzle of Strikes. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Gallas, A. and J. Nowak (2016) Mass Strikes in the Global Crisis.
Workers of the World, 1(8): 6–15.
Gallas, A., J. Nowak and F. Wilde (eds.) (2012) Politische Streiks
im Europa der Krise. Hamburg: VSA.
Gil, J. and R. Hernández (2014) La conflictividad laboral en
tiempos de crisis económica. Un análisis comparado de las huelgas
en el estado Español durante los sexenios 2002–2007 y 2008–2013.
Estudios, 4: 49–68.
Giraud, B. (2009) Des conflits du travail à la sociologie des
mobilisations: Les apports d’un décloisonnement empirique et
théorique. Politix, 22: 13–29.
González, S. and D. Luque (2014) ¿Adiós al corporatismo en España?
Pactos sociales en la crisis económica. Revista Española de
Investigaciones Sociológicas, 148: 79–101.
Graeber, D. (2012) Inside Occupy. Frankfurt am Main and New York:
Campus Verlag.
Groux, G. and J.-M. Pernot (2008) La grêve. Paris: Presses de
Sciences Po.
Gurr, T.R. (1969) A Comparative Study of Civil Strife. In Violence
in America: Historical and Comparative Perspectives, edited by D.
Graham and T.R. Gurr. New York: FA Praeger.
Hamann, K. (2005) Third Way Conservatism? The Popular Party and
Labour Relations in Spain. International Journal of Iberian
Studies, 18(2): 67–82.
Hernández, E. and H. Kriesi (2016) The Electoral Consequences of
the Financial and Economic Crisis in Europe. European Journal of
Political Research, 55(2): 203–224.
Hibbs, D.A. (1978) On the Political Economy of Long-Run Trends in
Strike Activity. British Journal of Political Science, 8(2):
153–175.
Hyman, R. (1975) Industrial Relations. A Marxist Introduction.
London: Macmillan.
International Labour Organization (ILO) (1993) Resolution
concerning Statistics of Strikes, Lockouts and Other Action due to
Labour Disputes. Available at
http://www.ilo.org/global/statistics-and-databases/standards-and-
guidelines/resolutions-adopted-by-international-conferences-of-labour-statisticians/WCMS_087544/lang-
-en/index.htm [accessed 16 January 2017].
International Labour Organization (ILO) (n.d.) ILOSTAT – Public
Sector Employment. Available at http://www.ilo.org/ilostat
[accessed 6 December 2016].
International Labour Organization (ILO) (n.d.) LABORSTA – Public
Sector Employment. Available at http://laborsta.ilo.org [accessed 6
December 2016].
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 39
Jackson, D., H.A. Turner and F. Wilkinson (1972) Do Trade Unions
Cause Inflation? Two Studies, with a Theoretical Introduction and
Policy Conclusion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Korpi, W. and M. Shalev (1979) Strikes, Industrial Relations and
Class Conflict in Capitalist Societies. British Journal of
Sociology, 30(2): 164–187.
Lacalle, J.D. (2015) Conflictividad y Crisis: España 2008–2013.
Barcelona: El Viejo Topo.
Luque, D. (2012a) Huelgas e intercambio político en España. Revista
Internacional de Sociología, 70(3): 561–585.
Luque, D. (2012b) Huelgas y crisis económica (y del intercambio
politico). Inguruak – Revista vasxa de sociología y de ciencia
política. 51: 95–113.
Luque, D. (2013) La forma de las huelgas en España, 1905–2010.
Política y Sociedad, 50(1): 235–268.
Luque, D., B. Cueto and F. Mato (2008) Un análisis regional de la
actividad huelgística en España. Revista Española de
Investigaciones Sociológicas, 124: 107–140.
Luque, D. and S. González (2016) El ciclo de protestas
anti-austeridad en España (2010–2014): Sindicatos, coaliciones y
estrategias. Paper presented at the XII Spanish Congress of
Sociology, Gijón, June 30 – July 2.
Nowak, J. and A. Gallas (2014) Mass Strikes against Austerity in
Western Europe – A Strategic Assessment, Global Labour Journal,
5(3): 306–321.
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (n.d.)
Short-term Labour Market Statistics. Available at
https://stats.oecd.org [accessed 16 January 2017].
Pizzorno, A. (1978) Political Exchange and Collective Identity in
Industrial Conflict. In The Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western
Europe Since 1968, Volume 2: Comparative Analyses, edited by C.
Crouch and A. Pizzorno. New York: Holmes & Meier.
Rees, A. (1952) Industrial Conflict and Business Fluctuations.
Journal of Political Economy, 60(5): 371–382.
Rist, C. (1907) La progression des grèves en France et sa valeur
symptomatique. Revue d'Economie politique, 21: 161–193.
Romanos, E. (2016) From Tahrir to Puerta del Sol to Wall Street:
The Transnational Diffusion of Social Movements in Comparative
Perspective. Revista Española de Investigaciones Sociológicas, 154:
103–118.
Salamon, M. (2000) Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice.
Essex: Pearson Education Limited.
Shorter, E. and C. Tilly (1971) The Shape of Strikes in France,
1830–1960. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 13(1):
60–86.
Shorter, E. and C. Tilly (1974) Strikes in France 1830–1968.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Silver, B. (2003) Forces of Labor: Workers’ Movements and
Globalization since 1870. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Skeels, J. (1971) Measures of United States Strike Activity.
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 24(4): 515–525.
Soskice, D. (1978) Strike Waves and Wage Explosions, 1968–1970: An
Economic Interpretation. In The Resurgence of Class Conflict in
Western Europe Since 1968, Volume 2: Comparative Analyses, edited
by C. Crouch and A. Pizzorno. New York: Holmes & Meier.
Spanish Ministry of Employment and Social Security (n.d.)
Estadística de huelgas y cierres patronales. Available at
http://www.empleo.gob.es/estadisticas/hue/welcome.htm [accessed 16
January 2017].
Global Labour Journal, 2018, 9(1), Page 40
Tixier, P.-E. (2007) Les mutations de la négotiation collective. Le
cas de la France. Négotiations, 8: 103–119.
Whiteley, P. (2016) What Explains Electoral Responses to the “Great
Recession” in Europe? Asian Journal of Comparative Politics, 1(1):
62–76.
BIOGRAPHICAL NOTE
NICHOLAS POHL is a PhD candidate in political sociology at the
University of Lausanne (IEPHI- CRAPUL). His thesis deals with
industrial conflict during the Great Recession in Spain, and aims
at bringing labour back into social movement studies. He is
co-supervised by Professor Olivier Fillieule, University of
Lausanne, and Professor Christine Walley, MIT Anthropology. [Email:
[email protected]]
<< /ASCII85EncodePages false /AllowTransparency false
/AutoPositionEPSFiles true /AutoRotatePages /None /Binding /Left
/CalGrayProfile (Dot Gain 20%) /CalRGBProfile (sRGB IEC61966-2.1)
/CalCMYKProfile (U.S. Web Coated \050SWOP\051 v2) /sRGBProfile
(sRGB IEC61966-2.1) /CannotEmbedFontPolicy /Error
/CompatibilityLevel 1.4 /CompressObjects /Tags /CompressPages true
/ConvertImagesToIndexed true /PassThroughJPEGImages true
/CreateJobTicket false /DefaultRenderingIntent /Default
/DetectBlends true /DetectCurves 0.0000 /ColorConversionStrategy
/CMYK /DoThumbnails false /EmbedAllFonts true /EmbedOpenType false
/ParseICCProfilesInComments true /EmbedJobOptions true
/DSCReportingLevel 0 /EmitDSCWarnings false /EndPage -1
/ImageMemory 1048576 /LockDistillerParams false /MaxSubsetPct 100
/Optimize true /OPM 1 /ParseDSCComments true
/ParseDSCCommentsForDocInfo true /PreserveCopyPage true
/PreserveDICMYKValues true /PreserveEPSInfo true /PreserveFlatness
true /PreserveHalftoneInfo false /PreserveOPIComments true
/PreserveOverprintSettings true /StartPage 1 /SubsetFonts true
/TransferFunctionInfo /Apply /UCRandBGInfo /Preserve /UsePrologue
false /ColorSettingsFile () /AlwaysEmbed [ true ] /NeverEmbed [
true ] /AntiAliasColorImages false /CropColorImages true
/ColorImageMinResolution 300 /ColorImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK
/DownsampleColorImages true /ColorImageDownsampleType /Bicubic
/ColorImageResolution 300 /ColorImageDepth -1
/ColorImageMinDownsampleDepth 1 /ColorImageDownsampleThreshold
1.50000 /EncodeColorImages true /ColorImageFilter /DCTEncode
/AutoFilterColorImages true /ColorImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG
/ColorACSImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1]
/VSamples [1 1 1 1] >> /ColorImageDict << /QFactor 0.15
/HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >>
/JPEG2000ColorACSImageDict << /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256
/Quality 30 >> /JPEG2000ColorImageDict << /TileWidth
256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >> /AntiAliasGrayImages false
/CropGrayImages true /GrayImageMinResolution 300
/GrayImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK /DownsampleGrayImages true
/GrayImageDownsampleType /Bicubic /GrayImageResolution 300
/GrayImageDepth -1 /GrayImageMinDownsampleDepth 2
/GrayImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeGrayImages true
/GrayImageFilter /DCTEncode /AutoFilterGrayImages true
/GrayImageAutoFilterStrategy /JPEG /GrayACSImageDict <<
/QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples [1 1 1 1] >>
/GrayImageDict << /QFactor 0.15 /HSamples [1 1 1 1] /VSamples
[1 1 1 1] >> /JPEG2000GrayACSImageDict << /TileWidth
256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >> /JPEG2000GrayImageDict
<< /TileWidth 256 /TileHeight 256 /Quality 30 >>
/AntiAliasMonoImages false /CropMonoImages true
/MonoImageMinResolution 1200 /MonoImageMinResolutionPolicy /OK
/DownsampleMonoImages true /MonoImageDownsampleType /Bicubic
/MonoImageResolution 1200 /MonoImageDepth -1
/MonoImageDownsampleThreshold 1.50000 /EncodeMonoImages true
/MonoImageFilter /CCITTFaxEncode /MonoImageDict << /K -1
>> /AllowPSXObjects false /CheckCompliance [ /None ]
/PDFX1aCheck false /PDFX3Check false /PDFXCompliantPDFOnly false
/PDFXNoTrimBoxError true /PDFXTrimBoxToMediaBoxOffset [ 0.00000
0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 ] /PDFXSetBleedBoxToMediaBox true
/PDFXBleedBoxToTrimBoxOffset [ 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 0.00000 ]
/PDFXOutputIntentProfile () /PDFXOutputConditionIdentifier ()
/PDFXOutputCondition () /PDFXRegistryName () /PDFXTrapped /False
/CreateJDFFile false /Description << /ARA
<FEFF06270633062A062E062F0645002006470630064700200627064406250639062F0627062F0627062A002006440625064606340627062100200648062B062706260642002000410064006F00620065002000500044004600200645062A064806270641064206290020064406440637062806270639062900200641064A00200627064406450637062706280639002006300627062A0020062F0631062C0627062A002006270644062C0648062F0629002006270644063906270644064A0629061B0020064A06450643064600200641062A062D00200648062B0627062606420020005000440046002006270644064506460634062306290020062806270633062A062E062F062706450020004100630072006F0062006100740020064800410064006F006200650020005200650061006400650072002006250635062F0627063100200035002E0030002006480627064406250635062F062706310627062A0020062706440623062D062F062B002E0635062F0627063100200035002E0030002006480627064406250635062F062706310627062A0020062706440623062D062F062B002E>
/BGR
<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>
/CHS
<FEFF4f7f75288fd94e9b8bbe5b9a521b5efa7684002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002065876863900275284e8e9ad88d2891cf76845370524d53705237300260a853ef4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f0062006100740020548c002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87248672c676562535f00521b5efa768400200050004400460020658768633002>
/CHT
<FEFF4f7f752890194e9b8a2d7f6e5efa7acb7684002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002065874ef69069752865bc9ad854c18cea76845370524d5370523786557406300260a853ef4ee54f7f75280020004100630072006f0062006100740020548c002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee553ca66f49ad87248672c4f86958b555f5df25efa7acb76840020005000440046002065874ef63002>
/CZE
<FEFF005400610074006f0020006e006100730074006100760065006e00ed00200070006f0075017e0069006a007400650020006b0020007600790074007600e101590065006e00ed00200064006f006b0075006d0065006e0074016f002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002c0020006b00740065007200e90020007300650020006e0065006a006c00e90070006500200068006f006400ed002000700072006f0020006b00760061006c00690074006e00ed0020007400690073006b00200061002000700072006500700072006500730073002e002000200056007900740076006f01590065006e00e900200064006f006b0075006d0065006e007400790020005000440046002000620075006400650020006d006f017e006e00e90020006f007400650076015900ed007400200076002000700072006f006700720061006d0065006300680020004100630072006f00620061007400200061002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e0030002000610020006e006f0076011b006a016100ed00630068002e>
/DAN
<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>
/DEU
<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>
/ESP
<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>
/ETI
<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>
/FRA
<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>
/GRE
<FEFF03a703c103b703c303b903bc03bf03c003bf03b903ae03c303c403b5002003b103c503c403ad03c2002003c403b903c2002003c103c503b803bc03af03c303b503b903c2002003b303b903b1002003bd03b1002003b403b703bc03b903bf03c503c103b303ae03c303b503c403b5002003ad03b303b303c103b103c603b1002000410064006f006200650020005000440046002003c003bf03c5002003b503af03bd03b103b9002003ba03b103c42019002003b503be03bf03c703ae03bd002003ba03b103c403ac03bb03bb03b703bb03b1002003b303b903b1002003c003c103bf002d03b503ba03c403c503c003c903c403b903ba03ad03c2002003b503c103b303b103c303af03b503c2002003c503c803b703bb03ae03c2002003c003bf03b903cc03c403b703c403b103c2002e0020002003a403b10020005000440046002003ad03b303b303c103b103c603b1002003c003bf03c5002003ad03c703b503c403b5002003b403b703bc03b903bf03c503c103b303ae03c303b503b9002003bc03c003bf03c103bf03cd03bd002003bd03b1002003b103bd03bf03b903c703c403bf03cd03bd002003bc03b5002003c403bf0020004100630072006f006200610074002c002003c403bf002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e0030002003ba03b103b9002003bc03b503c403b103b303b503bd03ad03c303c403b503c103b503c2002003b503ba03b403cc03c303b503b903c2002e>
/HEB
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
/HRV (Za stvaranje Adobe PDF dokumenata najpogodnijih za
visokokvalitetni ispis prije tiskanja koristite ove postavke.
Stvoreni PDF dokumenti mogu se otvoriti Acrobat i Adobe Reader 5.0
i kasnijim verzijama.) /HUN
<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>
/ITA
<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>
/JPN
<FEFF9ad854c18cea306a30d730ea30d730ec30b951fa529b7528002000410064006f0062006500200050004400460020658766f8306e4f5c6210306b4f7f75283057307e305930023053306e8a2d5b9a30674f5c62103055308c305f0020005000440046002030d530a130a430eb306f3001004100630072006f0062006100740020304a30883073002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e003000204ee5964d3067958b304f30533068304c3067304d307e305930023053306e8a2d5b9a306b306f30d530a930f330c8306e57cb30818fbc307f304c5fc59808306730593002>
/KOR
<FEFFc7740020c124c815c7440020c0acc6a9d558c5ec0020ace0d488c9c80020c2dcd5d80020c778c1c4c5d00020ac00c7a50020c801d569d55c002000410064006f0062006500200050004400460020bb38c11cb97c0020c791c131d569b2c8b2e4002e0020c774b807ac8c0020c791c131b41c00200050004400460020bb38c11cb2940020004100630072006f0062006100740020bc0f002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e00300020c774c0c1c5d0c11c0020c5f40020c2180020c788c2b5b2c8b2e4002e>
/LTH
<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>
/LVI
<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>
/NLD (Gebruik deze instellingen om Adobe PDF-documenten te maken
die zijn geoptimaliseerd voor prepress-afdrukken van hoge
kwaliteit. De gemaakte PDF-documenten kunnen worden geopend met
Acrobat en Adobe Reader 5.0 en hoger.) /NOR
<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>
/POL
<FEFF0055007300740061007700690065006e0069006100200064006f002000740077006f0072007a0065006e0069006100200064006f006b0075006d0065006e007400f300770020005000440046002000700072007a0065007a006e00610063007a006f006e00790063006800200064006f002000770079006400720075006b00f30077002000770020007700790073006f006b00690065006a0020006a0061006b006f015b00630069002e002000200044006f006b0075006d0065006e0074007900200050004400460020006d006f017c006e00610020006f007400770069006500720061010700200077002000700072006f006700720061006d006900650020004100630072006f00620061007400200069002000410064006f00620065002000520065006100640065007200200035002e0030002000690020006e006f00770073007a0079006d002e>
/PTB
<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>
/RUM
<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>
/RUS
<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>
/SKY
<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>
/SLV
<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>
/SUO
<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>
/SVE
<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>
/TUR <FEFF005900fc006b00730065006b0020006b0061006