22
First draft: please do not cite or circulate without authors’ permission. 1 Share it or lose it? Ethnic Inclusion and Authoritarian Stability. Keywords Authoritarian Stability, Regime Survival, Authoritarian Resilience, Ethnic Discrimina tion, Exclusion, Cooptation, Inclusion, Regime Breakdown Abstract In this paper, we examine the impact of ethnopolitical power struggles on au thoritarian stability. Competition for state power between ethnic groups has so far been an understudied factor within the literature on authoritarian regime survival. Although attempts to account for cooptation have recently gained prominence, most remain somewhat structuralist and merely focus on institu tions such as authoritarian parties, parliaments and elections as tools of coopta tion. Such institutional proxies lack a crucial account for grouplevel dynamics and build on the assumption that more cooptation mechanisms provide more stability. Focusing on ethnopolitical power struggles between included and ex cluded groups allows us to move one step closer to the actual locus of agency and to adopt a more dynamic perspective than has been the case in the previous lit erature. This paper will proceed in four steps. First, in relation to the existing literature we will illustrate how this research contributes to improve our understanding the effects of inclusion and exclusion on authoritarian stability. In the conceptual second part of the paper we will clarify our concepts before deriving our hypoth esis. Third, we will turn to the empirical part that contains methodological re marks and the results of our largen timeseries crosssection analysis. Finally we turn to our conclusions, before concluding some implications for further re search. Authors Ilyas Saliba is a PhD candidate at the Berlin Graduate School of Social Science (BGSS) at Humboldt University Berlin. He is a research fellow at the Berlin Social Science Center (WZB) in the research unit on Democracy and Democratization. Yannick Pengl is a PhD candidate at the Center for International and Comparative Studies at ETH Zürich. He is a Research Associate to the International Conflict Re search Group (ICR)

Share it or lose it? - European Consortium for Political ... it or lose it? ... LevitskyandWay2010;MagaloniandKricheli2010;Brownlee200 7;Geddes, ... Cederman,&Gleditsch,&and&Buhaug&2013;

  • Upload
    lenga

  • View
    220

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  1  

Share it or lose it? Ethnic Inclusion and Authoritarian Stability.

Keywords  Authoritarian  Stability,  Regime  Survival,  Authoritarian  Resilience,  Ethnic  Discrimina-­‐tion,  Exclusion,  Cooptation,  Inclusion,  Regime  Breakdown  

Abstract  In   this  paper,  we  examine   the   impact  of  ethno-­‐political  power  struggles  on  au-­‐thoritarian  stability.  Competition  for  state  power  between  ethnic  groups  has  so  far   been   an   understudied   factor   within   the   literature   on   authoritarian   regime  survival.   Although   attempts   to   account   for   cooptation   have   recently   gained  prominence,  most   remain   somewhat   structuralist   and  merely   focus   on   institu-­‐tions  such  as  authoritarian  parties,  parliaments  and  elections  as  tools  of  coopta-­‐tion.   Such   institutional   proxies   lack   a   crucial   account   for   group-­‐level   dynamics  and   build   on   the   assumption   that  more   cooptation  mechanisms   provide  more  stability.  Focusing  on  ethno-­‐political  power  struggles  between  included  and  ex-­‐cluded  groups  allows  us  to  move  one  step  closer  to  the  actual  locus  of  agency  and  to  adopt  a  more  dynamic  perspective  than  has  been  the  case  in  the  previous  lit-­‐erature.  This  paper  will  proceed  in  four  steps.  First,   in  relation  to  the  existing  literature  we  will   illustrate   how   this   research   contributes   to   improve   our   understanding  the  effects  of  inclusion  and  exclusion  on  authoritarian  stability.  In  the  conceptual  second  part  of  the  paper  we  will  clarify  our  concepts  before  deriving  our  hypoth-­‐esis.  Third,  we  will   turn   to   the   empirical   part   that   contains  methodological   re-­‐marks   and   the   results   of   our   large-­‐n   time-­‐series   cross-­‐section   analysis.   Finally  we  turn  to  our  conclusions,  before  concluding  some  implications  for  further  re-­‐search.  

Authors  Ilyas  Saliba  is  a  PhD  candidate  at  the  Berlin  Graduate  School  of  Social  Science  (BGSS)  at   Humboldt  University   Berlin.   He   is   a   research   fellow   at   the   Berlin   Social   Science  Center  (WZB)  in  the  research  unit  on  Democracy  and  Democratization.  

Yannick   Pengl   is   a   PhD   candidate   at   the   Center   for   International   and   Comparative  Studies   at   ETH   Zürich.  He   is   a   Research  Associate   to   the   International   Conflict   Re-­‐search  Group  (ICR)    

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  2  

Introduction  

In   this  paper,  we  examine   the   impact  of  ethno-­‐political  power  struggles  on  au-­‐

thoritarian  stability.  Competition  for  state  power  between  ethnic  groups  has  so  

far   been   an   understudied   factor   within   the   literature   on   authoritarian   regime  

survival.   Although   an   important   debate   within   conflict   research   (Bormann,  

Cederman,   and  Vogt   2013;   Cederman,   Gleditsch,   and  Buhaug   2013;   Cederman,  

Gleditsch,  and  Hug  2013;  Cederman,  Wimmer,  and  Min  2010;  Wucherpfennig  et  

al.   2011),   the   issue  of   the   inclusion  and  exclusion  of   ethnic   groups  has  not   yet  

found  its  way  into  the  study  of  authoritarianism.  

Implicitly,   some   of   the  more   recent  works   focusing   on   the   cooptation   of   elites  

and  the  role  of  formal  institutions  in  authoritarian  contexts  touch  upon  the  mat-­‐

ter   (Boix   and   Svolik   2013;   Bueno   de   Mesquita,   Smith,   and   Morrow   2003;  

Cheibub,   Gandhi,   and   Vreeland   2010;   Escribà-­‐Folch   and  Wright   2012;   Gandhi  

and  Przeworski  2007;  Gandhi  and  Przeworski  2006;  Gehlbach  and  Keefer  2012;  

Levitsky  and  Way  2013;  Magaloni  2008;  Malesky  and  Schuler  2010;  Morrow  et  

al.   2008;   Smith  2005;   Svolik  2009;   Svolik  2012;  Wright  2008;  Lust-­‐Okar  2004;  

Levitsky   and  Way   2010;  Magaloni   and  Kricheli   2010;   Brownlee   2007;   Geddes,  

Wright,  and  Frantz  2012;  Magaloni  2008).  However,  most  of  these  attempts  re-­‐

main   somewhat   structuralist   and  merely   focus   on   institutions   such   as   parties,  

parliaments  and  elections  as  tools  of  cooptation  in  authoritarian  regimes.  

Such   institutional   proxies   lack   a   coherent   group   concept   and   build   on   the   as-­‐

sumption  that  more  cooptation  mechanisms  provide  more  stability  without  tak-­‐

ing  the  role  of  discriminated  or  marginalized  groups  into  account.  Most  of  these  

works   rely   upon   various   kinds   of   behaviouralist  models   that   specify   idealized  

actor  categories.  Nonetheless  we  think  there  still  is  scope  for  improved  concepts  

and  operationalization.  The  authors  usually  make  claims  about  how  institutional  

settings  in  authoritarian  regimes  influence  the  regime  stability  through  allowing  

more  groups  to  gain  a  peace  of  the  cake.  However  the  dimension  of  group  level  

entities  remains  underspecified  in  most  studies.  Identifying  relevant  groups  and  

their   representation   in   political   regimes   enables   novel  ways   of   operationaliza-­‐

tion  of  cooptation  mechanisms  with  respect  to  previously  identified  relevant  ac-­‐

tor  groups  in  quantitative  analyses.  

We  regard  ethnic  groups  as  an  actor  type  particularly  relevant  to  the  question  of  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  3  

authoritarian  stability.  Focusing  on  ethno-­‐political  power  struggles  between  in-­‐

cluded  and  excluded  groups  allows  us  to  move  one  step  closer  to  the  actual  locus  

of  agency  and  to  adopt  a  more  dynamic  perspective  than  has  been  the  case  in  the  

previous  literature.  

The   aim  of   this  paper   is   to   address   a   gap   in   the   authoritarianism   literature  by  

borrowing   concepts   from   seminal  works   on   ethnic   conflicts  within   the   field   of  

political  violence  research.  By  highlighting  inclusionary  and  exclusionary  devel-­‐

opments  within  authoritarian  regimes  and  the  direct  or   indirect  effects  of  such  

moves  on  regime  stability.  Therefore   this  paper  contributes   to  a  debate  on   the  

impact  of   the  up-­‐  or  downgrading  of   certain   social   groups  on  authoritarian   re-­‐

gime  survival.  Our  approach  helps  to  increase  the  understanding  of  the  dynamics  

of   exclusionary  or   inclusionary  dynamics  on   regime  stability   in  autocratic   con-­‐

texts.  It  provides  a  novel  and  we  believe  more  suitable  way  of  modeling  the  role  

of   crucial   groups   in   authoritarian   regimes.  Thus  our  guiding   research  question  

reads  as  follows:  

RQ:  Does   inclusion  or  exclusion  of  politically  relevant  ethnic  groups   in  /   from  the  executive  influence  authoritarian  regime  survival?  

Following  Blattman  and  Miguel  in  their  approach  to  take  a  more  social  and  psy-­‐

chological  intake  on  grievances  (Blattman  &  Miguel  2010:  18f.)  we  aim  to  track  

down  if  and  how  exclusion  and  discrimination  on  ethnic  grounds  has  an  impact  

on   regime   stability.   Relying   on   a   body   of   literature   that   has   identified   ethnical  

marginalization,  discrimination,  and  exclusion  as  one  of  the  main  drivers  of  polit-­‐

ical   violence   we   aim   to   bring   the   political   violence   literature   into   the   field   of  

comparative  authoritarianism.  

Literature  and  Theory  

After  outlining  our  objectives  and  research  question,  we  will  briefly  refer  to  the  

contemporary  literature  in  the  following  section  of  this  paper.  First,  we  will  ad-­‐

dress   recent   research  on  cooptation   in  comparative  authoritarianism.  Doing  so  

we  emphasize  the  lack  of  agent  sensibility  in  the  current  literature  that  predom-­‐

inantly   focuses   on   institutional   set-­‐ups   to   explain   regime   survival   (Pepinsky  

2014,   1).   Second,  we   turn   to   research   on   ethnic   conflict   in   order   to   single   out  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  4  

how  their  approach  to  conceptualize   inclusion  and  exclusion  on  a  societal   level  

can  inform  the  study  of  authoritarian  regime  survival.  

After   this   overview  we   present   a   number   of   hypothesis   and   associated   causal  

mechanisms  deducted  in  order  to  overcome  the  operationalization  gap  in  the  in-­‐

stitutionalist   focused   literature   on   authoritarian   survival.  We   argue   that   intro-­‐

ducing   concepts   from   the   ethnic   conflict   literature   and   taking   another   level   of  

analysis   into  account  can  wield  new  insights  on  impacts  of   inclusion  and  exclu-­‐

sion  on  regime  stability.  Such  an  approach  is  expected  to  complement  previous  

analyses  focusing  on  structuralist  institutional  characteristics  as  it  offers  a  more  

actor  sensitive,  group  level  operationalization.  

A) Comparative  Authoritarianism  

Given  that  autocrats  are  driven  by  the  interest  in  their  own  endurance  in  power  

repression,   legitimacy   and   cooptation   are   the   three  dimensions   in  which   auto-­‐

crats   can   apply   measures   to   enhance   their   ability   to   stay   in   office   (Wintrobe  

1998;   Gerschewski   2013;   Merkel   and   Gerschewski   2012).   Recent   research   on  

authoritarian  regimes  has  focussed  on  the  role  of  institutions  in  non-­‐democratic  

contexts.  More   specifically,   the   ability   of   ruling   elites   instrumentalizing   formal  

institutions  to  include  potential  challengers  in  order  to  assure  their  allegiance  to  

the  regime.  Such  practices  have  been  intensely  studied  in  the  context  of  political  

parties  and  parliaments  that  serve  as  repositories  for  incorporating  political  ac-­‐

tors   and   groups   into   the   ruling   elite   (Bueno   de  Mesquita,   Smith,   and  Morrow  

2003;   Magaloni   2008;   Jennifer   Gandhi   and   Przeworski   2006;   Lust-­‐Okar   2004;  

Magaloni   and   Kricheli   2010;   Jennifer   Gandhi   2008;   Brownlee   2007;   Boix   and  

Svolik  2013).   In   sum,   cooptation   is  part  of   the   toolbox   that  stands   to   their  dis-­‐

posal  to  ensure  the  continuation  of  their  reign.  However  cooptation  practices  in  

authoritarian  regimes  have  been  researched  primarily  in  legislative  institutions  

(Magaloni  and  Kricheli  2010,  127).  This  “institutionalist  turn”  as  Pepinsky  (2014,  

1)  recently  put  it  has  gained  a  lot  of  attention  within  the  field  of  comparative  au-­‐

thoritarianism.  Nonetheless  Pepinsky  points  out  several  shortcomings  in  the  ex-­‐

isting   literature.   First,   he   questions   if   institutions   can   be   treated   as   exogenous  

causes   of   certain   political   outcomes   such   as   regime   breakdown   or   survival   in  

general.  This  critique  addresses  partly  an  inherent  endogeneity  problem  build  in  

the  research  on  cooptation  and  regime  stability,  as  effects  of   institutions   in  au-­‐

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  5  

thoritarian   regimes   cannot   be   treated   separately   from   strategies   of   regime  

maintenance   or   outcomes   of   survival   and   breakdown.   In   this   study  we   aim   to  

partially  account   for  this  critique.  As  Pepinsky  points  out  disentangling  coopta-­‐

tion  strategies  from  the  institutions  they  are  coopted  by  is  not  an  easy  undertak-­‐

ing.  Our  focus  on  the  executive  and  the  representation  on  the  group  level  might  

offer  a  more  direct  hint  towards  tracing  concrete  causal  pathways  of  inclusion  or  

exclusion   of   certain   relevant   political   groups   and   their   distinguishable   impact  

upon   regime   stability   or   instability.  Nevertheless  we   concede   that   this   critique  

can  only  be  addressed  by  a  comprehensive  multi-­‐method  study,  which  includes  

qualitative  case  studies  that  account  for  alternate  explanations  causal  pathways.    

Second,  Pepinsky  raises   the  question   if   the  narrow   functionalist  understanding  

of   complex   legislative   institutions   and   political   parties   underlying   most   argu-­‐

ments  of  current  research  can  be  upheld.  To  some  extend  such  instrumentalized  

understanding   of   parliaments   and   political   parties   in   authoritarian   regimes   is  

oversimplified  as  it  does  not  account  for  unintended  consequences  and  path  de-­‐

pendencies  that  might  develop  their  own  effects.  Furthermore  particularly  par-­‐

liaments  largely  are  outcomes  of  power  structures  although  they  are  prone  to  be  

subject  of  manipulation  they  can  rarely  solely  be  explained  as  outcomes  of  a  pre-­‐

determined  regime  strategy.  In  line  with  this  criticism  we  aim  to  develop  a  more  

actor-­‐centric  approach  to  the  study  of  cooptation.  Looking  into  dynamics  of  the  

executive   instead   of   parties   or   parliaments   is   fruitful   not   only   because   this   di-­‐

mension  is  oftentimes  overlooked  but  also  because  the  cabinet  as  the  head  of  the  

executive  tends  to  be  much  closer  to  the  center  of  any  ruling  elite  in  authoritari-­‐

an  regime  than  legislative  institutions.  Moreover  cabinets  tend  to  be  much  more  

directly  appointed  by  authoritarian  leaders  than  legislatures.  The  control  by  au-­‐

thoritarian   leaders   over   the   cabinet   and   its  members   is   expected   to   be   higher  

than  the  influence  on  the  outcomes  of  parliamentary  elections.  Focussing  on  the  

cabinet  thus  partly  circumvents  the  having  a  vague,  more  indirect  link  between  

the  leaders  preferences  and  the  inclusion  and  exclusion  of  certain  actors  into  the  

power   sharing   arrangement.   In   sum,   singling   out   politically   relevant   ethnic  

groups  and  their  specific  role  in  a  regime  measured  as  level  of  inclusion  or  exclu-­‐

sion   in  the  cabinet  makes  tracing  a   link  between  regime  action  and  its  stability  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  6  

via  inclusion  or  exclusion  into  the  cabinet  much  more  straight  forward  compared  

to  shifts  in  parliaments  or  parties.  

Including  challengers   in   institutions  of   the  executive  may   just  as  much  offer  an  

autocrat   the   possibility   to   coopt   relevant   political   actors   or   groups.   As   Arriola  

(2009)  has  shown  for  African  cases  an  executive  inclusion  strategy  might  allow  

for  more  control  over  the  included  groups  or   individuals  than  an  inclusion  into  

legislative  institutions  or  parties.  In  the  following  paragraphs  we  will   introduce  

the  literature  on  ethnic  conflict  in  order  to  justify  our  focus  on  ethnic  groups  as  a  

level  of  analysis  for  operationalizing  and  estimating  strategies  of  cooptation.  

B) Ethnic  Conflict  

As  mentioned  before  authoritarian   stability  depends  on  cooptation,  repression,  

and  legitimacy  (Merkel  and  Gerschewski  2012;  Gerschewski  2013).   In  multieth-­‐

nic   countries,   ethno-­‐political   inclusion   is   a   relevant   dimension   of   cooptation.  

This  dimension  has  so  far  been  overlooked  in  the  quantitative  literature  on  au-­‐

thoritarian   stability.  We   expect   that   ethnically   inclusive   authoritarian   regimes  

are  more  stable  than  their  more  exclusive  counterparts.  

Scholarly  work  on  ethnic  conflicts  has  highlighted  the  importance  of  ethnic  divi-­‐

sions   for   the   risk   of   conflict   onset   (Bormann,   Cederman,   and   Vogt   2013;  

Cederman,   Gleditsch,   and   Buhaug   2013;   Cederman,   Gleditsch,   and   Hug   2013;  

Cederman,  Wimmer,  and  Min  2010;  Wucherpfennig  et  al.  2011).  To  have  an  im-­‐

pact  upon  regime  survival  any  ethnic  cleavage  needs  to  have  political  relevance  

as  an  underlying  condition.  If  ethnic  affiliation  does  not  matter  for  the  (political)  

identity  of  any  given  actor  or  group  of  actors  then  the  expected  effects  of  inclu-­‐

sionary  or  exclusionary  dynamics  upon  regime  survival  are  expected  to  be  near  

irrelevant.  If  however  such  ethnic  cleavages  are  politicized  they  bare  near  explo-­‐

sive  potential  if  not  contained  by  the  ruling  elite  (Olzak  1983).  This  might  be  ac-­‐

complished  by  mechanisms  of  cooptation  through  inclusion  into  the  ruling  elite.  

Theories   of   ethnic  mobilization   provide   an   approach   to   explaining  why   power  

struggles  among  political  elites  are  often  fought  along  ethnic  lines.  On  the  most  

general   level,   ethnic   mobilization   arguments   claim   that   ethnic   groups   have   a  

comparative  advantage  vis-­‐à-­‐vis  other  social  groups  when  it  comes  to  organizing  

collective  action.  Most  frequently  related  to  the  literatures  on  social  movements  

and  contentious  politics  (Tilly  and  Tarrow  2006),  and  the  organization  of  rebel-­‐

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  7  

lion  (Weinstein  2006;  E.  J.  Wood  2003).  The  relevance  of  an  ethnic  dimension  on  

mobilization  and  rebellion  has  been  proven  irrespective  of  its  respective  regime  

type   context.  We  expect   that   in   authoritarian   regimes  ethnic   lines  matter   even  

more  because  such  regimes  tend  to  be  more  exclusive  than  democratic  ones  per  

se.  

The   importance   of   ethnic   groups   as   a   reference   framework   for   identity   and  

hence  political   representation  and   legitimacy   in   authoritarian   contexts   and  be-­‐

yond  is  expected  to  be  just  as  crucial  when  it  comes  to  regime  stability.  All  in  all  

we  stress,  that  ethnic  exclusion  or  inclusion  from  the  executive  in  authoritarian  

contexts  has  a  crucial  impact  on  regime  survival.  

Hypotheses  &  Causal  Mechanisms  

The  review  of  the  literature  suggests  applying  arguments  and  concepts  from  the  

ethnic  violence  literature  to  the  study  of  authoritarian  regimes  and  their  stabil-­‐

ity.  In  the  following  section  we  will  propose  two  sets  of  hypotheses  and  the  ex-­‐

pected   mechanisms   through   which   they   unfold   their   effect   (Coleman   1994).  

Those  are  subsequently  tested  with  a  quantitative  statistical  model.  

Despite  other  dimensions  of   regime  stability  such  as  repression  and   legitimacy  

playing  a  crucial  role   in  explaining  regime  survival  or  breakdown.  First,  we  ex-­‐

pect  more   inclusive   regimes   to   be  more   stable   than   less   inclusive   ones   due   to  

more  successful  cooptation  of  relevant  ethnic  groups.  

H1:   inclusion  of  relevant  ethnic  groups  in  cabinet   is  expected  to  be  indicate  effec-­‐tive  cooptation  and  thus  should  make  a  regime  more  stable.    

lower  regime  breakdown  probablity  

less  mobilization  along  ethnic  

lines    

relevant  ethnic  groups  are  represented  

inclusion  of  relevant  ethnic  

groups  

Figure  1  –  effect  of  inclusion  on  regime  stability  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  8  

H2:  Contrary,  exclusion  of  relevant  groups  is  expected  to  resemble  ineffective  coop-­‐tation  and  we  would  hence  expect  such  regimes  to  be  less  stable.  

Adopting   a   more   dynamic   perspective,   we   expect   changes   in   ethno-­‐political  

power  status  to  be  particularly  important  for  regime  stability.  The  downgrading  

or   exclusion   of   afore   included   group   is   expected   to   have   destabilizing   effects.  

Conversely,  we  expect   the  dynamics  of   inclusion  to  have  positive  effects  on  the  

survival  of  an  authoritarian  regime.  Fully  aware  that  cooptation  mechanisms  can  

only  account  for  partly  explaining  regime  survival  we  still  expect  an  independent  

effect  of  elite  cooptation  via  group  inclusion  on  regime  stability  or  vice  versa  for  

exclusion.  

In  the  following  we  will  provide  an  empirical  assessment  through  a  TCSC  logistic  

regression  including  controls  for  temporal  dependence  accounting  for  static  lev-­‐

els  of  inclusion  and  exclusion.  

Methodology,  Operationalization  &  Concepts  

Drawing   on   previous   studies  we   base   our   analysis   on   the   assumption   that   au-­‐

thoritarian   stability   is  based  on  multiple  pillars:  Cooptation,  repression,  and  le-­‐

gitimacy  (Gerschewski  2013).  We  then  focus  on  cooptation   in  multiethnic  socie-­‐

ties.  Our  main  argument  is  that  in  such  heterogeneous  countries  ethno-­‐political  

inclusion  is  a  relevant  dimension  of  cooptation.  This  dimension  has  so  far  been  

overlooked  in  the  quantitative  literature  on  cooptation  and  authoritarian  stabil-­‐

higher  regime  breakdown  probablity  

grievances  mobilize  along  ethnic  lines  

groups  demand  political  

representation    

exclusion  of  relevant  

ethnic  groups  

Figure  2  –  effect  of  exclusion  on  regime  stability  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  9  

ity.  We  will  now  go  on  to  test  whether  ethnically  inclusive  authoritarian  regimes  

are  more  stable  than  their  more  exclusive  counterparts.    

In   order   to   test   our   theoretical   argument   outlined   above,  we   run   simple   time-­‐

series   cross-­‐section   logistic   regression  models   including   controls   for   temporal  

dependence   as   recommended  by  Carter   and  Signorino   (2010).  While  more   ad-­‐

vanced  survival  analysis  methods  could  be  performed,  the  simple  method  chosen  

here  should  yield  equivalent  results  in  the  absence  of  strong  assumptions  about  

the  time  dependencies  of  the  baseline  hazard  of  regime  breakdown  as  well  as  the  

temporal  effect  of  the  various  predictors  (Beck,  Katz,  and  Tucker  1998).  

Our  sample  consists  of  all  multiethnic  countries  (i.e.  inhabited  by  more  than  one  

politically   relevant   ethnic   group)   under   authoritarian   rule.   Only   in  multiethnic  

states,  ethnic   inclusion  can  reasonably  be  expected  to  affect  regime  stability.   In  

defining  which   countries   count   as   autocratic,   we   rely   on   Cheibub,   Gandhi   and  

Vreeland   (2010)   and   Alvarez,   Cheibub,   Limongi   &   Przeworski   (2000),   respec-­‐

tively.  Due  to  data  limitations  in  some  of  our  control  variables,  our  analysis  is  re-­‐

stricted  to  the  period  from  1981  to  2009.  

Our  dependent  variable  is  an  authoritarian  regime  breakdown.  We  have  dummy  

coded  one  for  years  in  which  authoritarian  regime  collapses  and  zero  otherwise.  

Years   in   which   more   than   one   regime   collapsed   are   also   coded   as   one.   This  

means  that  we  lose  some  information,  but  if  anything,  ignoring  very  short-­‐lived  

regimes  should  produce  somewhat  more  conservative  estimates  of  the  effects  of  

our  main   independent   variables   (cf.   Escribà-­‐Folch   and  Wright   2010,   347   for   a  

similar  strategy).  

Our   choice  of   authoritarian   regimes   instead  of   leader   survival   or   authoritarian  

spells  as  unit  of  analysis  is  the  theoretically  most  appropriate  one  and  is  well  in  

line  with   recent  work  by  Svolik   (2012)  and   (Geddes,  Wright,   and  Frantz  2012;  

Geddes,  Wright,  and  Frantz  2013).  Cooptation  institutions  and  strategies  should  

have  an  effect  on  the  longevity  of  a  particular  regime,  not  necessarily  on  the  time  

in  office  of  one  particular  dictator.  Quite  obviously,  ethnic  inclusion  or  exclusion  

does  not  affect  the  odds  of  a  dictator  dying  in  a  given  year.  Neither  is  it  likely  to  

prevent  a  certain  rotation  scheme,  e.g.   in  a  military  governing  council,  from  op-­‐

erating.  A  focus  on  authoritarian  spells  would  be  equally  misleading,  since  they  

end  –by  definition–  in  a  democratic  transition  or  the  collapse  of  statehood.  These  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  10  

are,  of  course,  only  some,  and  certainly  not  the  most  frequent  forms,  of  authori-­‐

tarian  breakdown.  Thus,  we  look  at  authoritarian  regimes,  which  are  defined  as  

“a  set  of  formal  and/or  informal  rules  for  choosing  leaders  and  policies”  (Geddes,  

Wright,  and  Frantz  2013,  1).  As  soon  as  these  rules  are  replaced  by  another  set  of  

rules,  an  authoritarian  regime  breakdown  is  coded.  In  our  robustness  checks,  we  

additionally  rely  on  data  from  Svolik  (2012),  who  uses  a  slightly  different  coding  

scheme  and,  in  total,  codes  less  regime  changes  than  Barbara  Geddes  and  her  co-­‐

authors.1  

Our  main  explanatory  variable  is  Ethnic  Power-­‐sharing  (PS).  To  test  whether  our  

theoretical  expectation  that  ethnic  inclusiveness  fosters  stability  holds,  we  need  

to   operationalize   ethnic   inclusion.  We   do   so   in   three   different   ways.   First,   we  

construct   an   ethnic   power-­‐sharing   dummy   coded   one   for   all   country   years   in  

which  more  than  one  ethnic  group  has  access  to  executive  power.  This  is  a  very  

simple  operationalization,  but  in  multiethnic  states  it  captures  quite  well  wheth-­‐

er  at  least  some  degree  of  ethnic  inclusion  is  present.  Assuming  that  rational  au-­‐

thoritarian  elites  chose  their  ethnic  coalition  partners  with  an  eye  on  regime  sta-­‐

bility,   we   expect   a   negative   coefficient   on   this   variable   (Trebbi,   Rainer,   and  

Francois  2013).  The  data  comes  from  the  ETH  Zurich’s  EPR  data  set  (Cederman,  

Wimmer,  and  Min  2010).  

Our   second   operationalization  moves   beyond   a  mere   dichotomous   coding   and  

instead  seeks   to  measure   the  degree  of  ethnic   inclusiveness   in  a  given  country  

year.  It  is  constructed  as  the  logarithm  of  the  share  of  politically  relevant  groups  

that  are  included.  We  expect  that  the  more  of  the  relevant  groups  are  included,  

the  less  likely  ethnically  motivated  challenges  to  the  regime  become.  We  take  the  

logarithm  of   this  ration  because  we  expect  decreasing  marginal  utility  of   inclu-­‐

sion   (i.e.   including   the   sixth   group   brings   less   additional   stability   than  moving  

from  ethnic  monopoly  rule  to  power-­‐sharing  with  just  two  partners).  

Our  third  operationalization  of  ethnic  inclusiveness  interacts  the  power-­‐sharing  

dummy   described   above  with   the   share   of   the   ethnically   relevant   population  

represented  in  the  government  (PS*legippop).  This  is  another  way  of  testing  our  

theoretical  rational  that  the  more  representative  a  power-­‐sharing  coalition  is  of  

                                                                                                               1  Our  data  for  the  dependent  variable  thus  comes  from  Geddes,  Wright,  Frantz  (2013)  dataset.  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  11  

the  ethnically  relevant  population  in  the  respective  country,  the  more  stable  of  a  

regime  we  should  observe.  

When  it  comes  to  control  variables  we  have  tried  to  accommodate  for  alternative  

cooptation  explanations  as  well  as  explanations  of  regime  resilience  that  lie  with-­‐

in  other  pillars  of  authoritarian  stability.  

Alternative  mechanisms  of  cooptation  via  formal  legislative  institutions  are  con-­‐

trolled  for  by  including  dummies  for  the  presence  of  a  legislature,  a  single-­‐party  

or  a  multi-­‐party  system.  As  mentioned  before,  the  presence  of  legislative  body  is  

expected   to   serve   as   a   source   of   institutionalized   cooptation   of   relevant   elites  

(Cheibub,   Gandhi,   and   Vreeland   2010;   Jennifer   Gandhi   2008;   Cheibub,   Gandhi,  

and  Vreeland  2010).   Further,   successful   cooptation  heavily  depends  on   the   re-­‐

sources  available  to  any  given  authoritarian  regime.  Any  investigation  of  regime  

stability  thus  has  to  take  the  availability  of  resources  for  cooptation  into  account  

(Pace   2009;   Beck   2009).   We   do   so   through   controlling   for   the   respective   re-­‐

source  rents  per  capita  or  the  influx  of  aid  funds  that  may  be  used  to  buy  off  re-­‐

gime  opponents.23  

Concerning  repression  as  widely  accepted  in  the  authoritarianism  literature  we  

have   included   controls   soft   repression   and   hard   repression   (Davenport   and  

Inman  2012;  Davenport  2007).  Soft   repression   is   controlled   for  using  an   index  

ranging  from  0  to  14  indicating  to  which  extent  the  regime  respects  the  following  

rights:  “Foreign  Movement,  Domestic  Movement,  Freedom  of  Speech,  Freedom  of  

Assembly   &   Association,   Workers’   Rights,   Electoral   Self-­‐Determination,   and  

Freedom   of   Religion”   (Cingranelli   and   Richards   2010,   417).4  Accordingly   hard  

repression  is  operationalized  according  to  the  CIRI  Physical  Integrity  Index  rang-­‐

ing  from  0  to  8  indicating  to  what  extent  the  regime  resorts  to  “Torture,  Extraju-­‐

dicial  Killing,  Political  Imprisonment,  and  Disappearance.”  (Cingranelli  and  Rich-­‐

ards   1999,   417)5  Alternatively   we   tested   our   model   relying   upon   the   Political  

                                                                                                               2  Availability  of  resources  for  cooptation  (oil_gas_valuePOP_2000;  ODA_log)  3  Data  sources:  oil  &  gas  data  from  Ross  (2012),  aid  data  from  the  World  Bank’s  World  Development  Indicators.  

4  Soft  Repression  (new_empinx)  5  Hard  Repression  (physint;  StateDept)  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  12  

Terror  Scale  (PTS)  from  Gibney  and  colleagues  (Wood  and  Gibney  2010)  which  

did  not  alter  our  results.6  

Lastly  we  have  tried  to  control  our  results   for  effects  stemming  from  the  legiti-­‐

macy  of  the  regimes.  As  the  operationalization  and  measurement  of  legitimacy  in  

authoritarian  regimes  remains  problematic  we  have  decided  for  two  proxies  of-­‐

tentimes  relied  upon  in  the  literature.  Again  these  represent  two  dimensions  of  

regime   legitimacy   concept   as   adopted   from   Easton   (Easton   1965,   268;  

Gerschewski   2013,   20).   Output   legitimacy   (Scharpf   1998)   related   to   specific  

support  by   the   citizens   is   controlled   for  by   integrating   the   lagged   level   of  GDP  

growth  (Merkel  et  al.  2013).  The  input  dimension  of  legitimacy  or  diffused  sup-­‐

port  (Scharpf  1998;  Easton  1965)  that  are  defined  in   less  materialist   terms  are  

even  more  difficult  to  operationalize.  One  possibility  put  forward  by  (Chenoweth  

and  Stephan  2012)   is   to  control   for   the  absence  of   large-­‐scale  anti-­‐regime  pro-­‐

tests.  

Besides   the   controls   for   alternate   explanations   and   their   effects   upon   regime  

stability  we  have  included  a  standard  set  of  control  variables  such  as:  Population  

size   (logpop),   Recent   election   (election)7,  and   the   Politically   relevant  measure   of  

ethnic  diversity  (log_no_groups)  from  EPR,  which  includes  only  the  politically  rel-­‐

evant  ethnic  groups  and  not  all  present  ones  in  any  country  at  a  given  time.  Fur-­‐

thermore  we  have  conducted  an  alternative  specification   in  a  robustness  check  

with  the  ELF  index  (Alesina  et  al.  2003)  to  control  for  a  bias  in  our  ethnic  group  

measure.  

   

                                                                                                               6  Ranging  from  1  to  5  (highest  level  of  state  terror)  7  From  the  NELDA  data  set  (Hyde  and  Marinov  2012)  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  13  

Results  and  Conclusions  

The  coefficients  in  table  1  (model  1-­‐4)  on  the  PS  operationalizations  of  ethnic  in-­‐

clusiveness  are  negatively  signed  and  thus  are  in  line  with  our  theoretical  expec-­‐

tations  across  a  number  of  different  model  specifications.8  All  models  under  the  

PS   specification   and   remain   significant   at   the   95%   confidence   level   across   all  

models  (see  table  1).  

Table  1:  Logit  Analyses  of  Authoritarian  Regime  Breakdown,  1981-­‐2009  

Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1                                                                                                                    8  GWF  Dependent  Variable  (main  specification)  

 

(1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Ethnic Powersharing -0.823** -0.862** -0.816** -0.816** (0.373) (0.380) (0.377) (0.390) Legislature -0.972** (0.392) Single Party -0.296 (0.471) Multi-party 0.697 (0.498) Hard Repression -0.088 -0.090 -0.077 -0.045 (0.074) (0.070) (0.078) (0.083) Soft Repression 0.133** 0.157*** 0.123** 0.102* (0.053) (0.055) (0.057) (0.059) GDP per Capita 0.023 0.048 -0.004 -0.041 (0.215) (0.223) (0.220) (0.237) GDP Growth Rate -0.037*** -0.040*** -0.037*** -0.037*** (0.010) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011) Oil Rents -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Aid per Capita 0.0380 0.112 0.022 -0.007 (0.204) (0.201) (0.200) (0.207) Population Size 0.204 0.234 0.186 0.164 (0.178) (0.176) (0.176) (0.177) Number of Ethnic Groups 0.247 0.287 0.230 0.194 (0.342) (0.333) (0.343) (0.342) Election in t-1 -0.268 -0.204 -0.265 -0.285 (0.384) (0.388) (0.385) (0.384) Time 0.095 0.138** 0.103 0.102 (0.068) (0.067) (0.068) (0.068) Time2 -0.312 -0.427* -0.343 -0.348 (0.234) (0.239) (0.237) (0.233) Time3 0.027 0.035* 0.029 0.030 (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) Constant -6.149** -6.648** -5.678** -5.588* (2.821) (2.977) (2.893) (2.912) Observations 1,146 1,146 1,146 1,146

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  14  

Furthermore  the  egip_rel_log  variant  as   illustrated  in  table  2  models  1-­‐3  is  also  

negatively  signed  and  in  line  and  in  line  with  our  theoretical  expectations  across  

different  model  specifications  (table  2  model  1-­‐3).  The  confidence  level  of  these  

models  remains  at  the  95%  or  90%  confidence  interval  depending  on  the  specifi-­‐

cation.  

Table  2:  Logit  Analysis  of  Authoritarian  Breakdown,  1981-­‐2009  

(1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Share of groups included -2.077** -1.819* -1.801* (1.039) (1.013) (1.070) Ethnic Powersharing 0.528 (0.889) Share of rlvt. pop. included 0.317 (0.636) PS x included pop. -1.889* (1.121) Legislature -0.941** -1.012*** (0.394) (0.387) Single Party -0.286 (0.473) Multi Party 0.680 (0.500) Hard Repression -0.070 -0.057 -0.027 -0.085 (0.071) (0.079) (0.085) (0.071) Soft Repression 0.141*** 0.108* 0.087 0.161*** (0.053) (0.056) (0.057) (0.057) GDP per Capita 0.082 0.041 0.008 0.055 (0.226) (0.225) (0.241) (0.230) GDP Growth Rate -0.041*** -0.039*** -0.039*** -0.040*** (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.011) Oil Rents per Capita -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 -0.002 (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Aid per Capita 0.102 0.012 -0.016 0.146 (0.213) (0.212) (0.218) (0.205) Population Size 0.251 0.207 0.186 0.222 (0.178) (0.178) (0.178) (0.181) Number of Ethnic Groups -0.247 -0.262 -0.292 0.306 (0.345) (0.346) (0.350) (0.369) Election in t-1 -0.172 -0.229 -0.247 -0.229 (0.389) (0.385) (0.384) (0.390) Time 0.141** 0.106 0.106 0.152** (0.067) (0.067) (0.067) (0.067) Time2 -0.435* -0.354 -0.360 -0.479** (0.239) (0.235) (0.231) (0.238) Time3 0.036* 0.030 0.031 0.039* (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) (0.020) Constant -5.748* -5.049* -4.989 -6.983** (3.114) (3.057) (3.086) (3.119) Observations 1,145 1,145 1,145 1,146 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1    

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  15  

Additionally   the   interpretation   of   the   interaction   term   as   illustrated   in   table   2  

model  4  suggests  that  Power-­‐sharing  significantly  reduces  risk  of  regime  break-­‐

down  if  coalition  partners  represent  large  parts  of  the  country’s  politically  rele-­‐

vant  population.  Graph  1  below  depicts  this  effect  of  ethnic  power  sharing  which  

lowers  the  relative  risk  of  regime  failure  up  to  nearly  70%.  

Graph  1:  Average  marginal  effects  of  ethnic  power  sharing  

 

Finally,  we  conducted  a  number  of  robustness  checks  on  our  results  that  are  de-­‐

picted   in   table   3.   Taking   the   dataset   from   Svolik   on   regime   failures   as   the   de-­‐

pendent   variable   our   results   in   the  PS  measure   loses   significance,  whereas   the  

Egip_rel_log   models   remain   robustly   and   negatively   associated   with   regime  

breakdown.  Using  the  PTS  instead  of  CIRI  measure,  as  a  control  for  hard  repres-­‐

sion  does  not  alter   the  direction  or   the  significance  of  our   results,   they  remain  

robust.  Including  the  protest  variable  control  (Chenoweth  and  Stephan  2012)  as  

a   proxy   for   diffused   legitimacy   the   coefficients   on   the   PS   models,   and   the  

egip_rel_log  models  as  well  as  the  interaction  term  specification  remain  present,  

however  somewhat  smaller  and  less  significant.    

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  16  

Table  3:  Robustness  Checks  with  Regime  data  from  Svolik  (2012)  

(1) (2) (3) (4) VARIABLES Ethnic Powersharing -0.498 (0.560) Share of Groups included -2.587* -2.662* -2.483* (1.538) (1.551) (1.463) Legislature -0.416 (0.635) Single Party 0.702 (0.655) Multi-Party 0.079 (0.687) Hard Repression -0.151 -0.108 -0.142 -0.105 (0.096) (0.095) (0.110) (0.122) Soft Repression 0.077 0.096 0.115 0.082 (0.081) (0.090) (0.088) (0.091) GDP per Capita -0.352 -0.229 -0.186 -0.260 (0.343) (0.320) (0.331) (0.323) GDP Growth Rate -0.012 -0.017 -0.016* -0.016* (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) (0.010) Oil Rents per Capita -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Aid per Capita 0.473 0.530 0.567 0.483 (0.304) (0.368) (0.346) (0.342) Population Size 0.238 0.292 0.323 0.268 (0.235) (0.242) (0.241) (0.235) Number of Ethnic Groups -0.238 -0.712 -0.683 -0.680 (0.550) (0.455) (0.483) (0.477) Election in t-1 -0.678 -0.622 -0.684 -0.655 (0.627) (0.618) (0.648) (0.623) Time -0.211 -0.107 -0.138 -0.131 (0.238) (0.242) (0.248) (0.248) Time2 2.112 1.465 1.559 1.555 (1.941) (1.964) (2.009) (1.993) Time3 -0.608 -0.485 -0.492 -0.493 (0.445) (0.441) (0.457) (0.446) Constant -3.815 -4.313 -5.338 -3.996 (4.152) (4.101) (4.148) (3.946) Observations 1,311 1,308 1,308 1,308

Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

All  in  all  the  evidence  of  our  study  suggests  that  in  ethnically  diverse  countries,  

ethnically   inclusive   authoritarian   regimes   are   less   prone   to   breakdown   than  

their  exclusive  counterparts.    

Despite  the  strong  effects  of  ethnic  power  sharing  and  the  inclusion  of  politically  

relevant  ethnic  groups  across  all  models  we  have  found  some  caveats  interpret-­‐

ing  our  data  remain  important.  We  have  not  yet  come  up  with  a  theoretical  ex-­‐

planation   for   how   our   results   are   not   always   robust   against   the   use   of   other  

specifications  of  the  dependent  variable  and/or  all  control  variables.  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  17  

The  potential  endogeneity  problems  stemming   from  the   fact   that   the  degree  of  

inclusiveness  may  be  strategically  chosen  by  the  regime  as  a  maintenance  strate-­‐

gy  in  order  to  remain  in  power  and  thus  is  over  represented  in  only  in  inherently  

more  stable  regimes  is    a  major  problem  to  all  research  on  cooptation  (Pepinsky  

2014).  This  remains  an   issue  that  by  quantitative  methods  alone  cannot  be  ad-­‐

dressed  sufficiently.    

On  the  other  hand  just  as  the  danger  of  overestimating  the  effect  of  inclusiveness  

on  regime  stability   there   is  also  an  alternative  bias   to  our  results  based  on   the  

assumption   that   inclusion   only   appears   when   a   regime   already   is   threatened.  

Thus   an   expected   pattern  would   be   too   little,   too   late   inclusion   in   the   face   of  

crumbling  regime  stability.  For  our  results  this  then  would  mean  that  we  actually  

underestimate  the  true  causal  effect  of  inclusiveness  on  regime  stability.  Building  

on  our  results  and  the  aforementioned  caveats  we  will  turn  to  some  implications  

for   further  research   that  might  serve  as  a  guide   for  our  own   future  efforts  and  

those  of   others   estimating   effects   of   ethnic  heterogeneity   and   inclusiveness   on  

regime  survival.  

Implications  

Our  analysis  set  out  to  answer  the  question  if  the  inclusion  or  exclusion  of  politi-­‐

cally   relevant  ethnic  groups   in  /   from   the  executive   influence  authoritarian   re-­‐

gime  survival.  Our  results  confirm  a  strong  effect  of  ethnic  inclusion  in  the  execu-­‐

tive  on  authoritarian  survival  across  a  number  of  models  and  specifications.  This  

effect  to  a  large  extend  also  persists  if  we  include  an  array  of  controls  for  other  

typically  mentioned  explanations  of  regime  stability.  In  sum,  our  results  hint  to-­‐

wards   an   independent   and   relevant   effect   of   ethnic   inclusion   arrangements   in  

the  executive  on  authoritarian  survival.  

Nevertheless  the  data  only  indicates  a  correlation  between  the  two  phenomena.  

Which   means   that   in   order   to   prove   our   initial   hypotheses,   as   formulated   in  

mechanisms,  qualitative  case  study  research   is   inevitable.  Such  qualitative  case  

study  oriented  research  also  seems  necessary  in  order  to  tackle  the  most  immi-­‐

nent   endogeneity  problems   as  mentioned  before.   In-­‐depth   case   studies   at   best  

enable  a  look  beyond  the  big  picture  as  depicted  in  this  study  and  thus  allow  for  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  18  

tracing  the  mechanism  that  we  expect  underlies  the  correlations  observed  in  this  

study.  

Furthermore  a  combination  with  already  conducted  scholarly  works  on  coopta-­‐

tion  via  formal  legislative  institutions  might  offer  a  more  comprehensive  under-­‐

standing  of  cooptation  mechanisms  on  different  levels  and  dimensions  of  author-­‐

itarian  regimes  as  a  whole  and  their  impact  upon  regime  stability.  

Personally,  we  aim  at  integrating  a  dynamic  interaction  term  into  our  analysis  in  

order   to   further  disentangle   the   effects  of   actual  up  or  downgrading  of   certain  

ethnic  groups  and  the  effects  on  regime  survival  similarly  as  to  works  by  other  

researchers   in   the   field  of  ethnic   conflicts   (Cederman,  Wimmer,  and  Min  2010;  

Cederman,  Gleditsch,   and  Buhaug  2013).  Moreover   this   study  will   be   extended  

by  an  illustrative  case  study  from  the  MENA  region,  which  “[…]  has  not  only  been  

the  worlds  most   undemocratic   but   also   the  most   ethnically   exclusive   and   dis-­‐

criminatory”  (Bormann,  Cederman,  and  Vogt  2013,  2).9  

   

                                                                                                               9  For  a  definition  of  politically  included  and  excluded  groups  please  refer  to  Cederman,  Wimmer  and  Min  2010:  100f.  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  19  

References  

Alesina,  Alberto,  Arnaud  Devleeschauwer,  William  Easterly,  Sergio  Kurlat,  and  Romain  Wacziarg.  2003.  “Fractionalization.”  Journal  of  Economic  Growth  8  (2):  155–94.  doi:10.1023/A:1024471506938.  

Alvarez,  Micheal  E.,  José  Antonio  Cheibub,  Fernando  Limongi,  and  Adam  Prze-­‐worski.  2000.  Democracy  and  Development:  Political  Institutions  and  Well-­‐Being  in  the  World,  1950-­‐1990.  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Arriola,  Leonardo  R.  2009.  “Patronage  and  Political  Stability  in  Africa.”  Compara-­‐tive  Political  Studies  42  (10):  1339–62.  doi:10.1177/0010414009332126.  

Beck,  Martin.  2009.  “Rente  Und  Rentierstaat  Im  Nahen  Osten.”  In  Der  Nahe  Osten  Im  Umbruch,  25–49.  Springer.  http://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-­‐3-­‐531-­‐91890-­‐7_2.  

Beck,  Nathaniel,  Jonathan  N.  Katz,  and  Richard  Tucker.  1998.  “Taking  Time  Seri-­‐ously:  Time-­‐Series-­‐Cross-­‐Section  Analysis  with  a  Binary  Dependent  Vari-­‐able.”  American  Journal  of  Political  Science  42  (4):  1260–88.  doi:10.2307/2991857.  

Boix,  Carles,  and  Milan  W.  Svolik.  2013.  “The  Foundations  of  Limited  Authoritari-­‐an  Government:  Institutions,  Commitment,  and  Power-­‐Sharing  in  Dicta-­‐torships.”  The  Journal  of  Politics  75  (02):  300–316.  doi:10.1017/S0022381613000029.  

Bormann,  Nils-­‐Christian,  Lars-­‐Erik  Cederman,  and  Manuel  Vogt.  2013.  “Ethnona-­‐tionalist  Cleavages  in  Civil  Wars:  Allah’s  Wrath  or  Babel’s  Legacy?”  

Brownlee,  Jason.  2007.  Authoritarianism  in  an  Age  of  Democratization.  1  edition.  Cambridge  England ;  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Bueno  de  Mesquita,  Bruce,  Alastair  Smith,  and  James  D.  Morrow.  2003.  The  Logic  of  Political  Survival.  Cambridge,  MA:  MIT  Press.  

Carter,  David  B.,  and  Curtis  S.  Signorino.  2010.  “Back  to  the  Future:  Modeling  Time  Dependence  in  Binary  Data.”  Political  Analysis  18  (3):  271–92.  doi:10.1093/pan/mpq013.  

Cederman,  Lars-­‐Erik,  Kristian  Skrede  Gleditsch,  and  Halvard  Buhaug.  2013.  Ine-­‐quality,  Grievances,  and  Civil  War.  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Cederman,  Lars-­‐Erik,  Kristian  Skrede  Gleditsch,  and  Simon  Hug.  2013.  “Elections  and  Ethnic  Civil  War.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  46  (3):  387–417.  doi:10.1177/0010414012453697.  

Cederman,  Lars-­‐Erik,  Andreas  Wimmer,  and  Brian  Min.  2010.  “Why  Do  Ethnic  Groups  Rebel?:  New  Data  and  Analysis.”  World  Politics  62  (1):  87–119.  

Cheibub,  José  Antonio,  Jennifer  Gandhi,  and  James  Raymond  Vreeland.  2010.  “Democracy  and  Dictatorship  Revisited.”  Public  Choice  143  (1-­‐2):  67–101.  doi:10.1007/s11127-­‐009-­‐9491-­‐2.  

Chenoweth,  Erica,  and  Maria  J.  Stephan.  2012.  Why  Civil  Resistance  Works:  The  Strategic  Logic  of  Nonviolent  Conflict.  Reprint  edition.  New  York:  Columbia  University  Press.  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  20  

Cingranelli,  David  L.,  and  David  L.  Richards.  2010.  “The  Cingranelli  and  Richards  (CIRI)  Human  Rights  Data  Project.”  Human  Rights  Quarterly  32  (2):  401–24.  doi:10.1353/hrq.0.0141.  

Coleman,  James.  1994.  Foundations  of  Social  Theory.  Cambridge,  MA:  Harvard  University  Press.  

Davenport,  C.  2007.  “State  Repression  and  the  Tyrannical  Peace.”  Journal  of  Peace  Research  44  (4):  485–504.  doi:10.1177/0022343307078940.  

Davenport,  Christian,  and  Molly  Inman.  2012.  “The  State  of  State  Repression  Re-­‐search  Since  the  1990s.”  Terrorism  and  Political  Violence  24  (4):  619–34.  doi:10.1080/09546553.2012.700619.  

Easton,  David.  1965.  A  Systems  Analysis  of  Political  Life.  New  York:  Wiley  &  Sons.  Escribà-­‐Folch,  Abel,  and  Joseph  Wright.  2010.  “Dealing  with  Tyranny:  Interna-­‐

tional  Sanctions  and  the  Survival  of  Authoritarian  rulers1.”  International  Studies  Quarterly  54  (2):  335–59.  

———.  2012.  “Authoritarian  Institutions  and  Regime  Survival:  Transitions  to  Democracy  and  Subsequent  Autocracy.”  British  Journal  of  Political  Science  42  (02):  283–309.  doi:10.1017/S0007123411000317.  

Gandhi,  J.,  and  A.  Przeworski.  2007.  “Authoritarian  Institutions  and  the  Survival  of  Autocrats.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  40  (11):  1279–1301.  doi:10.1177/0010414007305817.  

Gandhi,  Jennifer.  2008.  Political  Institutions  under  Dictatorship.  Cambridge:  Cam-­‐bridge  University  Press.  http://bibliothek.wzb.eu/fulltext/toc_text/2011/pv-­‐102351.pdf.  

Gandhi,  Jennifer,  and  Adam  Przeworski.  2006.  “Cooperation,  Cooptation,  and  Re-­‐bellion  Under  Dictatorships.”  Economics  &  Politics  18  (1):  1–26.  doi:10.1111/j.1468-­‐0343.2006.00160.x.  

Geddes,  Barbara,  Joseph  Wright,  and  Erica  Frantz.  2012.  “New  Data  on  Autocratic  Regimes.”  Manuscript,  September.  http://dictators.la.psu.edu/pdf/pp10.pdf.  

———.  2013.  “New  Data  on  Autocratic  Breakdown  and  Regime  Transitions.”  http://dictators.la.psu.edu/pdf/gwf-­‐code-­‐book-­‐1.1.  

Gehlbach,  Scott,  and  Philip  Keefer.  2012.  “Private  Investment  and  the  Institution-­‐alization  of  Collective  Action  in  Autocracies:  Ruling  Parties  and  Legisla-­‐tures.”  The  Journal  of  Politics  74  (02):  621–35.  doi:10.1017/S0022381611001952.  

Gerschewski,  Johannes.  2013.  “The  Three  Pillars  of  Stability:  Legitimation,  Re-­‐pression,  and  Co-­‐Optation  in  Autocratic  Regimes.”  Democratization  20  (1):  13–38.  doi:10.1080/13510347.2013.738860.  

Hyde,  S.  D.,  and  N.  Marinov.  2012.  “Which  Elections  Can  Be  Lost?”  Political  Analy-­‐sis  20  (2):  191–210.  doi:10.1093/pan/mpr040.  

Levitsky,  Steven,  and  Lucan  Way.  2013.  “The  Durability  of  Revolutionary  Re-­‐gimes.”  Journal  of  Democracy  24  (3):  5–17.  

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  21  

Levitsky,  Steven,  and  Lucan  A.  Way.  2010.  Competitive  Authoritarianism.  Hybrid  Regimes  after  the  Cold  War.  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Lust-­‐Okar,  Ellen.  2004.  “Divided  They  Rule:  The  Management  of  Political  Opposi-­‐tion.”  Comparative  Politics  36  (2):  159–79.  

Magaloni,  Beatriz.  2008.  “Credible  Power-­‐Sharing  and  the  Longevity  of  Authori-­‐tarian  Rule.”  Comparative  Political  Studies  41  (4-­‐5):  715–41.  doi:10.1177/0010414007313124.  

Magaloni,  Beatriz,  and  Ruth  Kricheli.  2010.  “Political  Order  and  One-­‐Party  Rule.”  Annual  Review  of  Political  Science  13  (1):  123–43.  doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.031908.220529.  

Malesky,  Edmund,  and  Paul  Schuler.  2010.  “Nodding  or  Needling:  Analyzing  Del-­‐egate  Responsiveness  in  an  Authoritarian  Parliament.”  American  Political  Science  Review  104  (03):  482–502.  doi:10.1017/S0003055410000250.  

Merkel,  Wolfgang,  and  Johannes  Gerschewski.  2012.  “Autocracies  at  Critical  Junc-­‐tures:  A  Model  for  the  Study  of  Dictatorial  Regimes”.  Wissen-­‐schaftszentrum  Berlin  für  Sozialforschung.  

Merkel,  Wolfgang,  Christoph  Stefes,  Alexander  Schmotz,  Johannes  Gerschewski,  and  Dag  Tannenberg.  2013.  “Why  Do  Dictatorships  Survive?”  In  PVS  Spe-­‐cial  Issue.  Politischr  Vierteljahresschrift.  Nomos  verlag  für  Sozialwissen-­‐schaften.  

Morrow,  James  D.,  Bruce  Bueno  De  Mesquita,  Randolph  M.  Siverson,  and  Alastair  Smith.  2008.  “Retesting  Selectorate  Theory:  Separating  the  Effects  of  W  from  Other  Elements  of  Democracy.”  American  Political  Science  Review  102  (03):  393–400.  doi:10.1017/S0003055408080295.  

Olzak,  S.  1983.  “Contemporary  Ethnic  Mobilization.”  Annual  Review  of  Sociology  9  (1):  355–74.  doi:10.1146/annurev.so.09.080183.002035.  

Pace,  Michelle.  2009.  “Paradoxes  and  Contradictions  in  EU  Democracy  Promotion  in  the  Mediterranean:  The  Limits  of  EU  Normative  Power.”  Democratiza-­‐tion  16  (1):  39–58.  doi:10.1080/13510340802575809.  

Pepinsky,  Thomas.  2014.  “The  Institutional  Turn  in  Comparative  Authoritarian-­‐ism.”  British  Journal  of  Political  Science  Forthcoming.  

Ross,  Michael  L.  2012.  “Replication  Data  for:  ‘The  Oil  Curse.’”  http://hdl.handle.net/1902.1/17976  UNF:5:2/XXuAZgPPzb4giDLlgjqQ==  Princeton  University  Press  [Distributor]  V1  [Version].  

Scharpf,  Fritz  W.  1998.  Interdependence  and  Democratic  Legitimation.  MPIfG  working  paper.  http://www.econstor.eu/handle/10419/41689.  

Smith,  Benjamin.  2005.  “Life  of  the  Party:  The  Origins  of  Regime  Breakdown  and  Persistence  under  Single-­‐Party  Rule.”  World  Politics  57  (03):  421–51.  doi:10.1353/wp.2006.0004.  

Svolik,  Milan  W.  2009.  “Power  Sharing  and  Leadership  Dynamics  in  Authoritari-­‐an  Regimes.”  American  Journal  of  Political  Science  53  (2):  477–94.  doi:10.1111/j.1540-­‐5907.2009.00382.x.  

———.  2012.  The  Politics  of  Authoritarian  Rule.  Cambridge  University  Press.    

First  draft:  please  do  not  cite  or  circulate  without  authors’  permission.  

  22  

Tilly,  Charles,  and  Sidney  Tarrow.  2006.  Contentious  Politics.  Oxford,  Oxon,  UK:  Oxford  University  Press.  

Trebbi,  Francesco,  Ilia  Rainer,  and  Patrick  Francois.  2013.  “The  Dictator�s  Inner  Circle.”  Forthcoming,  November.  http://www.ire.eco.usi.ch/en/progetti/cetem/paper-­‐trebbi-­‐221682.pdf.  

Weinstein,  Jeremy  M.  2006.  Inside  Rebellion:  The  Politics  of  Insurgent  Violence.  1  edition.  Cambridge ;  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Wintrobe,  Ronald.  1998.  The  Political  Economy  of  Dictatorship.  Auflage:  New.  Cambridge,  UK ;  New  York,  NY:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Wood,  Elisabeth  Jean.  2003.  Insurgent  Collective  Action  and  Civil  War  in  El  Salva-­‐dor.  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Wood,  Reed  M.,  and  Mark  Gibney.  2010.  “The  Political  Terror  Scale  (PTS):  A  Re-­‐Introduction  and  a  Comparison  to  CIRI.”  Human  Rights  Quarterly  32  (2):  367–400.  doi:10.1353/hrq.0.0152.  

Wright,  Joseph.  2008.  “Do  Authoritarian  Institutions  Constrain?  How  Legisla-­‐tures  Affect  Economic  Growth  and  Investment.”  American  Journal  of  Polit-­‐ical  Science  52  (2):  322–43.  doi:10.1111/j.1540-­‐5907.2008.00315.x.  

Wucherpfennig,  Julian,  Nils  B.  Weidmann,  Luc  Girardin,  Lars-­‐Erik  Cederman,  and  Andreas  Wimmer.  2011.  “Politically  Relevant  Ethnic  Groups  across  Space  and  Time:  Introducing  the  GeoEPR  Dataset.”  Conflict  Management  and  Peace  Science  28  (5):  423–37.  doi:10.1177/0738894210393217.