44
Explaining Sudden Spikes in Global Risk 1 Philippe Bacchetta University of Lausanne CEPR Eric van Wincoop University of Virginia NBER November 9, 2010 1 We would like to thank Martina Insam for able research assistance, Michael Dev- ereux and Fabio Ghironi for their comments, as well as other participants at the ECB conference \What Future for Financial Globalization?" for questions and comments. We gratefully acknowledge nancial support from the National Science Foundation (grant SES-0649442), the Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research, the National Centre of Competence in Research \Financial Valuation and Risk Management" (NCCR FIN- RISK), and the Swiss Finance Institute.

Explaining Sudden Spikes in Global Risk - …people.virginia.edu/~ev4n/papers/open_risk_panics_Nov_8.pdfExplaining Sudden Spikes in Global Risk1 Philippe Bacchetta University of Lausanne

  • Upload
    vuanh

  • View
    214

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Explaining Sudden Spikes in Global

Risk1

Philippe Bacchetta

University of Lausanne

CEPR

Eric van Wincoop

University of Virginia

NBER

November 9, 2010

1We would like to thank Martina Insam for able research assistance, Michael Dev-

ereux and Fabio Ghironi for their comments, as well as other participants at the ECB

conference “What Future for Financial Globalization?” for questions and comments. We

gratefully acknowledge financial support from the National Science Foundation (grant

SES-0649442), the Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research, the National Centre

of Competence in Research “Financial Valuation and Risk Management” (NCCR FIN-

RISK), and the Swiss Finance Institute.

Abstract

The sharp drop in equity prices across the globe during the 2008 financial crisis

coincides with a spike in equity price risk (VIX) of similar magnitude across a broad

set of developing and developed countries. This spike in risk across many countries

appears unrelated to a sudden shift in fundamentals and does not appear to be the

result of a transmission of shocks across countries through financial markets. In

this paper we provide an explanation for this phenomenon by developing a model

that allows for the possibility of large self-fulfilling shifts in risk. This builds on

Bacchetta, Tille and van Wincoop (2010), who develop the concept of risk panics in

a closed economy framework. During such a panic a weak macro variable becomes

a focal point (coordination device) for a self-fulfilling increase in perceived risk.

We show that when macro fundamentals have a limited impact on equity prices

during normal times, the risk panic will impact countries very similarly.

1 Introduction

The financial panic in the Fall of 2008 lead to a sharp drop in equity prices and an

increase in perceived risk around the world. It has been widely documented that

the magnitude of the equity price decline was broadly similar across the globe.

What is perhaps less known is that the spike in asset price risk, as measured by

implied volatility measures (e.g., VIX in the US), was also of similar magnitude

across a broad set of countries. This is illustrated in Figure 1 for a group of

12 developed and developing countries.1 The close co-movement in equity prices

during this period was clearly related to the co-movement in risk. Beyond the

recent crisis, there is a substantial econometric literature which has shown that

asset price volatility co-moves significantly across countries, especially during high

volatility periods.2

Two features stand out regarding the global spike in risk during recent financial

crises. First, it is hard to attribute to a sudden shift in fundamentals. The health

of leveraged financial institutions was weak during the panic in the Fall of 2008,

but had gradually deteriorated for at least a year prior to that. The same can be

said for the spike in global risk during the Spring of 2010 that has been associated

with the health of the Greek public sector. The fiscal problems in Greece had

developed for a long time and did not suddenly arise in the Spring of 2010. The

second feature is that the global spike in risk does not appear to be the result of a

transmission of shocks across countries through financial linkages. As documented

by Rose and Spiegel (2010) and Kamin and Pounder (2010), there is no evidence

that countries with larger cross-border financial linkages to the United States saw

a bigger drop in equity prices during the 2008 crisis.

The goal of this paper is to develop a framework that is consistent with these

stylized facts. We aim to develop a model that generates a sharp spike in risk

simultaneously across the globe, that is not the result of sudden large fundamental

shocks, and whose global dimension is not associated with the transmission of

shocks through financial markets. In our model a global risk panic takes the form

of a self-fulfilling increase in risk perceptions around the world that occurs when a

1Data sources are reported in Appendix C.2See for example Edwards and Susmel (2001), Beirne et al. (2009) or Diebold and Yilmaz

(2009). Soriano and Climent (2006) provide a survey of this literature.

1

particularly weak macro variable in some country becomes the sudden focal point

of the market.

The paper builds on Bacchetta, Tille, and van Wincoop (2010), from here on

BTW, who develop the concept of risk panics in a closed economy context. BTW

show that as long as asset demand depends on asset price risk, self-fulfilling shifts

in risk are possible. In this case there is a dynamic mapping of risk into itself,

because the risk associated with the future asset price depends on uncertainty

about future risk. During a risk panic, a weak fundamental suddenly takes on the

additional role of a coordination device for the self-fulfilling shift in risk. BTW

show that the weaker the fundamental, the larger is the panic.

Some of the recent literature on financial contagion, which we review in Section

2, has explained the co-movement in equity prices during recent crises with the

co-movement in risk premia. This focus is well placed as it is hard to argue that

either of the two other asset pricing determinants, the risk-free rate and expected

dividends, can account for the equity price co-movement. But movements in risk

play little or no role in the risk premia considered in the literature.

In this paper we also attribute equity price co-movement to co-movement in risk

premia. But, motivated by the stylized facts presented in the opening paragraphs,

we depart from the recent literature along three important dimensions. First, in

our model fluctuations in risk premia (and especially their spikes during a panic)

are explicitly linked to fluctuations in asset price risk itself. This is motivated by

the sharp increase in equity price risk across the globe during the recent crises,

as documented in Figure 1. Understanding the fluctuations in asset price risk,

and their commonality across countries, then becomes the central aspect of our

analysis.

Second, in our theory the co-movement in equity price risk is not a result of

the transmission of a shock in one country to other countries. Rather, some event

draws the attention of investors around the globe to a variable (or set of variables)

in a particular country, such as the health of financial institutions in the United

States or fiscal debt in Greece. When this variable is particularly weak, it can lead

to a simultaneous panic across the globe, with a widespread increase in perceived

equity price risk and drop in equity prices. This aspect of our model is consistent

with the fact that regular transmission channels through financial markets do not

appear to have played a central role.

2

Third, in our model a panic generates entirely self-fulfilling shifts in risk and

equity prices while the recent contagion literature relies on shocks to observed

macro fundamentals (i.e., technology shocks). As emphasized above, the panic in

the Fall of 2008 came quite unexpectedly and is hard to attribute to a sudden large

shock to macro fundamentals.

We want to emphasize that our model is not aimed at providing a full account

of what happened during the 2008 panic. Most observers would argue that a key

aspect of the crisis was a run on wholesale bank deposits (e.g. through repo con-

tracts), an aspect that is entirely absent from our model. Security complexity

issues and adverse selection combined to generate a sharp increase in haircuts on

many asset backed securities, reducing their values and making them effectively in-

eligible as collateral. We believe that it is important to distinguish what happened

in the equity market from what happened to asset backed securities. Security

complexity issues did not apply to equity and only a small fraction of the equity

market was held by these leveraged financial institutions. Moreover, when global

risk more than tripled in the Spring of 2010, there was no bank panic at all. There

just needs to be some variable, or set of variables, that becomes a natural focal

point of the market and generates a level of “fear” that implies a self-fulfilling

increase in perceived risk. It is no wonder that the VIX is often referred to as the

“fear factor”.

The particular model that we use to derive our results is sufficiently stylized to

allow for a closed form analytical solution. This makes the mechanisms at work

easier to understand for what is otherwise a quite difficult topic. We consider a two-

country model where investors trade equity claims with exogenous and stochastic

dividends. Two simplifying assumptions are an OLG structure and a constant

interest rate on bonds. BTW show that relaxing the latter assumption is not

central to risk panics.

The only stochastic fundamental is the dividend on equity. The role this fun-

damental plays during a panic is as a coordination device for a self-fulfilling shift

in risk. As emphasized by BTW, the precise nature of the macro variable that be-

comes the focal point for a risk panic is not so important. They show that results

are similar when the key macro fundamental is the net worth of leveraged financial

institutions, which fits more closely to the 2008 crisis. Focusing on stochastic div-

idends as the only source of macro shocks has the advantage of making the model

3

more standard and analytically tractable.

We analyze the factors that determine how much individual countries are af-

fected by the global panic. An important dimension is the hedging property of a

country asset with respect to the global portfolio. If assets have similar hedging

properties, their price collapse in a panic will be of similar magnitude. We show

that a condition for these hedging properties to be similar is that macro funda-

mentals have limited explanatory power for equity prices during normal times. In

that case a global risk panic can affect countries similarly.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the

recent literature on financial contagion. Section 3 describes the model. Section 4

discusses the solution for the world equity price and global risk panics. Section

5 discusses the solution of the equity prices of the two countries. It particularly

it focuses on how a global risk panic affects the countries individually. Section 6

concludes.

2 Related Literature

In this section we discuss two related literatures. The first is the recent literature

on financial contagion. The second is the general literature on multiple equilibria

and self-fulfilling shifts in expectations.

2.1 Recent Financial Contagion Literature

The recent financial crisis has spurred renewed interest in the issue of financial

contagion.3 The vast existing literature4 is being extended, drawing lessons from

recent events. This renewed interest in contagion is not surprising as movements

in equity prices across the globe were highly synchronized during the Fall of 2008.

A striking feature however, especially in light of Figure 1, is that the theoretical

literature gives little attention to asset price risk. Co-movement of asset prices is

not associated in the literature with co-movements of risk.

3There is no precise or agreed-upon definition of contagion, but we think of it as a situation

where a shock in one country affects other countries through various channels.4See Dornbusch et al. (2000) or Karolyi (2003) for surveys.

4

Nonetheless the recent crisis has lead the literature to put more emphasis on

common shifts in risk premia to explain asset price co-movements. These shifts

in risk premia are not associated with asset price risk itself, but rather operate

through wealth effects often due to financial frictions. This channel was suggested

by Calvo (1999) in the context of the Russian virus and later by Krugman (2008) to

explain the co-movement of equity prices during the recent crisis.5 More formally

in general equilibrium frameworks, this channel of contagion appears in Gromb

and Vayanos (2002), Kyle and Xiong (2001) and Pavlova and Rigobon (2008).

To understand this wealth channel, assume that the Home equity price goes

down, for example due to a negative earnings shock. This reduces the wealth of

Home investors, which reduces their demand for Foreign equity through a wealth

effect. Similarly, to the extent that Foreign investors hold Home equity, it also

reduces their wealth, which again reduces demand for Foreign equity. This leads

to a drop in the Foreign equity price. Risk premia and wealth are related as

reduced wealth implies that the holdings of risky assets increase relative to wealth.

This leads to higher risk premia.

This explanation for contagion during the recent crisis has an important limi-

tation though. The contagion relies critically on the presence of large cross-border

asset holdings. However, Rose and Spiegel (2010) and Kamin and Pounder (2010)

find that larger cross-border asset exposure to the U.S. did not increase the extent

to which stock prices were affected by the crisis. This has lead to a search for

additional contagion channels operating through risk premia that do not depend

on the extent of cross-border asset holdings.6

Dedola and Lombardo (2010) develop a model where financial intermediaries

charge an “external finance premium” to investors, which is basically a risk pre-

mium. As investors’ wealth decreases (negative technology shock), a higher risk

premium on both Home and Foreign equity implies a common drop in their prices.

The extent of equity price risk does not affect the finance premium, which is only

5In Calvo (1999), price movements are exacerbated by imperfect information by investors.

See King and Wadwhani (1990) or Calvo and Mendoza (2000) for models explaining contagion

based on limited information.6While Rose and Spiegel (2010) and Kamin and Pounder (2010) consider the impact of the

crisis on stock prices across countries, most of the empirical literature on contagion in the recent

financial crises focuses on the impact on real variables like output growth. See for example Lane

and Milesi-Ferretti (2010), Imbs (2010), or Giannone et al. (2010).

5

an exogenous function of wealth. A similar mechanism is present in Devereux

and Yetman (2010) and Mendoza and Quadrini (2010). In Devereux and Yetman

(2010) investors face a leverage or borrowing constraint. A lower wealth implies a

tighter constraint and higher risk premia on all risky assets held by investors. This

is because the borrowing constraint makes no distinction between the riskiness of

Home versus Foreign equity.

In these papers the implied risk premia are the same for Home and Foreign

equity independently of the extent of cross-border asset holdings. However, this

is essentially by assumption as the finance premium or the borrowing constraint

makes no distinction between the riskiness of Home and Foreign assets. In reality

borrowing constraints depend on the riskiness of the assets held by investors as

well as their exposure to individual assets. This is true both for collateralized

and uncollateralized lending. Risk premia will then differ across assets. Conta-

gion through wealth effects will again depend on the extent of cross-border asset

holdings. For example, a drop in Home wealth should raise risk premia on Foreign

stock more when Home investors allocate more of their wealth to Foreign equity

and are therefore more at risk of default with a drop in Foreign equity prices.

A few papers do examine the impact of shocks to uncertainty occurring on

one asset. For example, Fostel and Geneakoplos (2008) present a model where an

increase in uncertainty in a developed country’s assets leads to a price decline in

emerging country asset prices. Schinasi and Smith (2000) examine the impact of

a volatility increase in one asset under various portfolio rules and determine when

contagion occurs. These papers, however, consider exogenous changes in risk and

do not lead to co-movement in asset price risk.

2.2 Self-Fulfilling Expectations

Also related is the broader literature on self-fulfilling shifts in expectations. In this

literature there is a coordination of beliefs among agents, such that a common shift

in beliefs leads to actions of all agents that make the change in expectations self-

fulfilling. In terms of asset prices, there are many applications of this phenomenon

for both stock prices and exchange rates.7

7In particular, there is a large literature with self-fulfilling speculative attacks on currencies,

e.g., see Obstfeld (1986) or Aghion et al. (2004).

6

There can also be contagion across countries associated with self-fulfilling shifts

in beliefs. For example, Masson (1999) argues that a currency crisis in one country

can trigger a self-fulfilling shift in beliefs in another country that leads to a currency

crisis there. Similarly, there can be simultaneous bank runs in multiple countries

due to self-fulfilling shifts in beliefs. Allen and Gale (2000) examine contagion in

a Diamond-Dybvig model. Although they do not analyze self-fulfilling shifts in

beliefs, it is well known that they can arise in this context. There can either be a

common self-fulfilling shift in beliefs across countries or a self-fulfilling bank run in

one country that is transmitted to other countries through cross-country linkages

between banks.

In this paper there are also self-fulfilling shifts in beliefs, but a key distinction is

that beliefs are associated with asset price risk. This is critical as we wish to explain

the global spike in risk that is common across many countries. Related, but quite

different from what we do here, is a small literature in which self-fulfilling shifts

in beliefs about risk can occur due to an interaction between risk and liquidity.

This occurs in limited participation models such as Pagano (1989), Allen and Gale

(1994) and Jeanne and Rose (2002). When agents believe that risk is high, market

participation is low. This implies low market liquidity, which leads to a large price

response to asset demand shocks and therefore high risk.8

In this paper the self-fulfilling shift in beliefs about risk is of a very different

nature. In the high risk equilibrium risk is time-varying, while it is constant in the

limited participation models. This connects better to the recent financial crises

during which there was a spike not only in the level but also the volatility of the

VIX. The possibility of a high risk equilibrium is not associated with the interaction

between risk and liquidity, but rather is the result of the dynamic nature of the

model where risk today depends on uncertainty about risk tomorrow. A shift to

the high risk equilibrium implies a self-fulfilling shift in beliefs about the entire

stochastic process of risk. This process is linked to that of a macro fundamental.

This fits closely to what we have seen during recent crises. For example, the VIX

fluctuated significantly during the Greek debt crisis with every bit of information

about a possible bailout package.

8This phenomenon is not limited to limited participation models of asset prices. For other

applications see Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2006) and Walker and Whiteman (2007).

7

3 A Simple Two-Country Portfolio Choice Model

In this section we describe a simple two-country portfolio choice model. Each

country, Home and Foreign, is inhabited by two-period overlapping generations of

consumers-investors with mean-variance preferences. They allocate their portfolio

between bonds, Home stocks and Foreign stocks.9 Financial markets are perfectly

integrated. The only uncertainty comes from Home and Foreign shocks that affect

dividends. In this section, we derive the optimal portfolios and the equilibrium

conditions for equity prices. The equilibria themselves are discussed in the next

two sections.

3.1 Optimal Portfolios

The model complexity is kept to a strict minimum so that it can be solved an-

alytically. We denote the Home and Foreign countries respectively H and F. In

both countries the overlapping generations of investors are born with wealth W .10

They invest it in equity and bonds and consume the return on their investment

when old. The total number of agents is n in the Home country and 1− n in the

Foreign country.

The bond pays an exogenous constant gross return R. This implicitly assumes

that there is a risk-free technology with a constant real return R that is in infinite

supply. This short-cut assumption allows us to derive a closed form solution to

the model.11 Equity consists of a claim on trees with stochastic dividends of

respectively ZH,t and ZF,t in the Home and Foreign countries. The per capita

capital stock (number of trees) in both countries is K. Equity prices are QH,t and

QF,t. Home and Foreign equity returns from t to t+ 1 are then

RH,t+1 =ZH,t+1 +QH,t+1

QH,t

(1)

9There is no distinction between Home and Foreign bonds as it is a single good economy.10As discussed in BTW, the assumption of OLG with initial endowments contributes to simplify

the analysis by reducing the number of state variables. However, numerical analysis shows that

relaxing this assumption does not affect fundamentally the results.11In BTW we relax it in a closed economy setting by introducing a time-varying interest rate

solved from bond market equilibrium. While this requires a numerical solution as a result of the

non-linearities that it generates, it does not fundamentally alter the findings.

8

RF,t+1 =ZF,t+1 +QF,t+1

QF,t

(2)

The only source of uncertainty in the model is with respect to dividends:

ZH,t = Z +mAH,t (3)

ZF,t = Z +mAF,t (4)

where Z is a positive constant, m is a non-negative parameter, and AH,t and AF,t

are Home and Foreign macro variables. The formulation of (3) and (4) allows

us to vary the fundamental role of the macro variables AH,t and AF,t in affecting

asset payoffs. As m becomes smaller, both dividends and asset prices become less

affected by fundamental shocks. When m = 0, the variables AH,t and AF,t no longer

affect dividends. They then becomes pure sunspots that have no fundamental role

in the model. The macro variables follow an AR process:

Ai,t+1 = ρAi,t + εi,t+1 (5)

i = H,F . The innovations εH,t+1 and εF,t+1 have symmetric distributions with

mean zero. Their variance is σ2 and their correlation is ρHF . Also assume that

vart(ε2i,t+1) = ω2, i = H,F .

Investors from both countries born at time t maximize a mean-variance utility

over their portfolio return:

EtRpt+1 − 0.5γvart(R

pt+1) (6)

As explained in BTW, the adoption of mean-variance preferences is a simplifying

device to make asset demand, and therefore asset prices, depend on future asset

price risk. This will also be the case when we introduce financial constraints in an

expected utility framework, such as value-at-risk or margin constraints, but the

resulting setup will be far more complex. As we will see, the link between asset

prices and future asset price risk is key to generating self-fulfilling shifts in risk.

The two countries are perfectly integrated, so that they choose the same port-

folio allocation and have the same portfolio returns:

Rpt+1 = αH,tRH,t+1 + αF,tRF,t+1 + (1− αH,t − αF,t)R (7)

where αi,t denotes the portfolio share invested in equity from country i.

9

The equity market clearing conditions are

αH,tW = QH,tnK (8)

αF,tW = QF,t(1− n)K (9)

3.2 Equilibrium Conditions for Equity Prices

Maximization of (6) with respect to αH,t and αF,t gives

αH,t =1

γ

vart(RF,t+1)Et(RH,t+1 −R)− covt(RH,t+1, RF,t+1)Et(RF,t+1 −R)

vart(RH,t+1)vart(RF,t+1)− covt(RH,t+1, RF,t+1)2(10)

αF,t =1

γ

vart(RH,t+1)Et(RF,t+1 −R)− covt(RH,t+1, RF,t+1)Et(RH,t+1 −R)

vart(RH,t+1)vart(RF,t+1)− covt(RH,t+1, RF,t+1)2(11)

Write the excess payoff on stocks as ri,t+1 = Qi,t+1+Zi,t+1−RQi,t for i = H,F .

Substituting the portfolio expressions (10)-(11) into the market clearing conditions

(8)-(9) then gives

vart(rF,t+1)EtrH,t+1 − covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1)EtrF,t+1 =

γnK

W

(vart(rH,t+1)vart(rF,t+1)− covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1)2

)(12)

vart(rH,t+1)EtrF,t+1 − covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1)EtrH,t+1 =

γ(1− n)K

W

(vart(rH,t+1)vart(rF,t+1)− covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1)2

)(13)

In solving the model we will use the approach proposed by Aoki (1981), first

analyzing world aggregates and then differences across countries. Define the world

equity price as QW,t+1 = nQH,t+1 + (1−n)QF,t+1 and the global dividend payment

as ZW,t+1 = nZH,t+1 + (1− n)ZF,t+1. The excess payoff on a world equity claim is

then

rW,t+1 = nrH,t+1 + (1− n)rF,t+1 = QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1 −RQW,t

Writing (12)-(13) jointly in vector notation and then pre-multiplying them with

the matrix vart(rH,t+1) covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1)

covt(rH,t+1, rF,t+1) vart(rF,t+1)

gives

EtrH,t+1 =γK

Wcovt(rH,t+1, rW,t+1) (14)

EtrF,t+1 =γK

Wcovt(rF,t+1, rW,t+1) (15)

10

The equilibrium expected excess payoff on equity, which is a risk premium, depends

on the covariance with the excess payoff on the world equity claim.12

Taking the weighted sum of (14) and (15), with weights n and 1 − n, as well

as their simple difference, gives

EtrW,t+1 =γK

Wvart(rW,t+1) (16)

Et(rH,t+1 − rF,t+1) =γK

Wcovt(rH,t+1 − rF,t+1, rW,t+1) (17)

These two equations are key to solving for the equilibrium asset prices. (16) tells

us that the risk premium on the global equity position depends on the variance

of the global excess payoff. Equation (17) simply says that investors demand a

higher expected excess payoff on the equity that has a higher covariance with the

world. Risk premia also depend on risk aversion γ, on the asset supply K and on

wealth W , but they are constant in the analysis.

Returning to our notation in terms of equity prices, if we define QD,t = QH,t−QF,t as the difference in equity price, (16)-(17) become

Et(QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1)−RQW,t =γK

Wvart(QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) (18)

Et(QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1)−RQD,t =γK

Wcovt(QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1, QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) (19)

Using (18) and (19) we now solve for QW,t and QD,t as a function of the state

variables AH,t and AF,t. This also gives the solution for the equity prices of the

individual countries. In the next section we focus on the world price QW,t, while

we examine individual prices in Section 5.

4 World Equity Price: Multiple Equilibria and

Panics

The solution for the world equity price can be obtained from (18) alone. This

equation is the same as the equilibrium in the closed economy model of BTW,

12These last two equations imply the familiar capital asset pricing model. Using that rW,t+1 =

nrH,t+1 + (1 − n)rF,t+1, they can be written as Etri,t+1 = βiEtrw,t+1 for i = H,F , where

βi = covt(ri,t+1, rw,t+1)/vart(rW,t+1).

11

where agents can invest in a single stock and in bonds. Not surprisingly, the

nature of the equilibria resulting from (18) is the same as in BTW. There are three

types of equilibria: a pure fundamental equilibrium, sunspot-like equilibria, and

equilibria that allow for self-fulfilling switches between low and high risk states.

We first describe the basic mechanism behind the multiplicity of equilibria and

then discuss the three types of equilibria.

4.1 Basic Mechanism

A key feature of equation (18) is that the price QW,t at time t is related to the

variance of the price at time t + 1, vart(QW,t+1). Equation (18) can be rewritten

as:

QW,t =1

REtZW,t+1 +

1

REtQW,t+1 −

γK

W

1

Rvart(QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) (20)

The asset price today depends not only on expectations and on risk associated

with future dividends, but also on risk associated with the future world equity

price itself. Define this risk as Riskt = vart(QW,t+1). It is this dependence of the

equity price on risk associated with its future level that creates the possibility of

multiple equilibria and self-fulfilling shifts in risk.

QW,t depends negatively on Riskt. But sinceQW,t+1 in turn depends on Riskt+1,

Riskt depends on uncertainty associated with Riskt+1. Risk does not just depend

on uncertainty about future dividends, but also on uncertainty about future risk

itself. The fact that risk depends on uncertainty about future risk gives rise to

a degree of freedom about the process of risk. This leads to multiple equilibria,

characterized by different beliefs about the process of risk. It also gives rise to the

possibility of self-fulfilling shifts in beliefs about the process of risk.

In the remainder of this section we discuss the three types of equilibria that

are possible. First, there is a fundamental equilibrium in which agents believe that

risk is constant. Second, there is a sunspot-like equilibrium where beliefs about

risk are tied to a macro fundamental.13 In this case the macro fundamental has a

dual role as a fundamental (in this model by affecting the dividend on assets) and

as a coordination device for beliefs about risk. The latter role is entirely separate

from the fundamental role and is made possible by the degree of freedom about

risk perceptions due to the dynamic link between future risk and current risk.

13The terminology of sunspot-like equilibria was first introduced by Manuelli and Peck (1992).

12

In our model this dual role can be played by AH,t or AF,t or some linear combina-

tion, each generating a different sunspot-like equilibrium. For illustrative purposes,

in what follows we will only consider sunspot-like equilibria where AH,t plays this

dual role. While dividends are the only fundamentals in our simple model, BTW

show that other fundamentals, such as the net worth of leveraged institutions, can

take on this dual role as well. In principle, any macro variable can take on the

role as coordination device for beliefs about risk. During the recent European debt

crisis, one can argue that the Greek debt played such a role.

The third type of equilibrium is a switching equilibrium, which allows for self-

fulfilling switches between the fundamental equilibrium and the sunspot-like equi-

librium. During this switch there is a self-fulfilling shift in beliefs about the process

of risk. When a switch occurs from the fundamental to the sunspot-like equilib-

rium, we speak of a risk panic. Risk then spikes and more so when the fundamental

is weak. We now turn to a detailed description of each of these three equilibria.

4.2 Fundamental Equilibrium

First consider an equilibrium where the world equity price is linear in the two

fundamentals:14

QW,t = QW + vWHAH,t + vWFAF,t (21)

where QW , vWH and vWF are constants to be solved. This implicitly assumes that

perceived risk is constant over time. Using (21), we can compute the expectation

and variance of QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1. Notice that the variance is constant in this case.

Substituting the result into (18), and equating on the left and the right hand side

the constant term, the term linear in AH,t and the term linear in AF,t, allows us

to solve for the three unknown parameters.

The solution is (see Appendix A for details of the algebra and for an expression

for the constant term QW ):

vWH =nmρ

R− ρ (22)

vWF =(1− n)mρ

R− ρ (23)

14In considering such stationary equilibria, we automatically rule out rational bubbles.

13

so that

QW,t = QW +mρ

R− ρAW,t (24)

where AW,t+1 = nAH,t+1 + (1 − n)AF,t+1. The world equity price depends on the

world dividend, whose impact is larger the higher the persistence ρ of dividend

shocks. We call this the fundamental equilibrium. The coefficient on AW,t goes to

zero as we let m→ 0, in which case AW,t no longer plays a fundamental role (does

not affect the global dividend).

4.3 Sunspot-like Equilibrium

We now consider a sunspot-like equilibrium where beliefs about risk are time-

varying and the Home fundamental AH,t plays the role of a coordination device for

beliefs about risk. We can find such an equilibrium by conjecturing a solution of

the type

QW,t = QW + vWHAH,t + vWFAF,t + VWHA2H,t (25)

In comparison to (21) this equilibrium conjecture has an additional term that is

quadratic in the Home fundamental. This quadratic term captures the role of AH,t

as a variable around which beliefs about risk are coordinated.

We again use the method of undetermined coefficients to solve for the para-

meters of the conjectured solution. We first use (25) to compute the expectation

and variance of QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1. Substituting the result into (18) and equating

on the left and the right hand side the constant term, the term linear in ZH,t, the

term linear in ZF,t, and the term quadratic in ZH,t, allows us to solve for the four

unknown parameters. Algebraic details are left to Appendix A. The solution is

(leaving again the constant term to the Appendix):

VWH = − W

γK

R− ρ24ρ2σ2

(26)

vWH = − m

1− ρ

[n+

R− ρ2R− ρ ρHF (1− n)

](27)

vWF =(1− n)mρ

R− ρ (28)

The key parameter here is VWH , which multiplies A2H,t in the equilibrium world

equity price. When VWH is non-zero, as is clearly the case, then perceived risk in

14

this equilibrium is time-varying and depends on AH,t:

vart(QW,t+1) = (vWH + 2VWHρAH,t)2σ2 + v2WFσ

2 +

2vWF (vWH + 2VWHρAH,t)σ2ρHF + V 2

WHρ2ω2 (29)

The role of AH,t in coordinating beliefs about risk is entirely separate from its role

as a fundamental. This can be seen by letting m go to zero. As m = 0, AH,t has

no fundamental role at all. But VWH does not depend on m, so the role of AH,t in

driving time-varying perceptions of risk is unrelated to its fundamental role.15

We call this equilibrium a sunspot-like equilibrium, and the variable AH,t a

sunspot-like variable, because AH,t has a role similar to that of a sunspot. AH,t

clearly is not a pure sunspot as it affects the Home dividend when m > 0, but

its role in coordinating beliefs about risk is exactly the same as that of a sunspot

variable. The term VWHA2H,t would be the same if AH,t were a pure sunspot.

Even though AH,t plays a fundamental role when m > 0, this role is always

significantly dominated by its sunspot role. This is reflected not only in the term

that is quadratic in AH,t, which exclusively reflects the sunspot role of AH,t, but

also in the linear term in AH,t in the world equity price. The coefficient vHW in the

linear term in AH,t actually has a negative sign, as opposed to a positive sign in

the fundamental equilibrium. This change in sign is due to the covariance between

the fundamental dividend risk and the self-fulfilling shifts in risk.16

For illustrative purposes, Figure 2 shows both the fundamental and sunspot-like

equilibria for a particular parameterization (at the bottom of Figure 2). It shows

how the world equity price and risk depend on the Home fundamental AH,t. Risk

is defined as the standard deviation of QW,t+1 divided by QW,t. For the purpose

of the Figure we assume that εH,t only takes on the values −σ and +σ. It is

15Remarkably, a lower γ raises the absolute size of VWH . Intuitively, lower risk aversion implies

that agents are less responsive to shifts in risk, which makes it easier to have an equilibrium with

high and volatile beliefs about risk. A similar argument can also explain why lower persistence

ρ increases the magnitude of VWH . For further discussion, see BTW.16An increase in AH,t raises the expected excess payoff due to the persistent increase in the

dividend. In equilibrium there has to be an offsetting drop in the expected excess payoff or

increase in risk. In the fundamental equilibrium vWH > 0 does the job as it raises the current

equity price, which lowers the expected excess payoff. But in the sunspot-like equilibrium, vWH <

0 does the job as it raises risk. This is because the variance of vWHAH,t+1 + VWHA2H,t+1 has

the linear term 4vWHVWHρσ2AH,t, which depends positively on AH,t when vWH < 0.

15

important that the distribution is bounded as AH,t itself is then bounded as well

(here between plus and minus σ/(1− ρ)), which is needed to assure that the asset

price is positive in all states.

In the sunspot-like equilibrium the equity price and risk are clearly much more

sensitive to AH,t. The additional risk leads to a lower world equity price than under

the fundamental equilibrium for all possible values of AH,t. At the extreme values

of AH,t (on either side) there are very high beliefs about risk and correspondingly

low equity prices.

4.4 Switching Equilibria and Global Risk Panics

We refer to the third type of equilibrium as a switching equilibrium. This equi-

librium is the main focus of this paper. It is closely related to the fundamental

and sunspot-like equilibria discussed so far. In a switching equilibrium, there are

occasional self-fulfilling switches between low and high risk states. The low risk

state is similar to the fundamental equilibrium and the high risk state is similar to

the sunspot-like equilibrium. We assume that the switch between low and high risk

states is driven by a Markov process. With probability p1 we are in the low risk

state tomorrow when we are in the low risk state today. Similarly, with probability

p2 we are in the high risk state tomorrow if we are in the high risk state today.

When p1 = p2 = 1, we always remain in the same state, leading to the funda-

mental and sunspot-like equilibria discussed above. When we lower the probabil-

ities below one, agents need to take into account that we may switch to another

state when computing expectations and risk. The low and high risk states then

no longer correspond exactly to the fundamental and sunspot-like equilibria. For

example, risk is higher in the low risk state than in the fundamental equilibrium

as there is now a possibility of switching to the high risk state. The relationship

between the equity price and the state variables remains as in (25), but ones needs

to separately solve for the coefficients in the low and high risk states.

BTW solve for such switching equilibria. Here we take a somewhat simpler

approach, with the benefit of the findings in BTW. They show that the solution is

a continuous function of the probabilities. As p1 = p2 approaches 1, the low and

high risk states approach respectively the fundamental and sunspot-like equilibria.

Using this finding, we consider the low risk state to be the fundamental equilibrium

16

and the high-risk state the sunspot-like equilibrium. This is infinitesimally close

to the true equilibrium when p1 = p2 are very close to 1. While the probabilities

of switching are then very small, we can still consider the impact of a switch. This

approach has the advantage that we already know what the low and high risk

states are. For larger switching probabilities (lower values of p1 and p2) a solution

can only be obtained numerically. The qualitative results remain similar though.

A risk panic involves a self-fulfilling switch from the low risk state to the high

risk state. At the moment the panic happens there is an immediate increase in

perceived risk, coordinated around AH,t. In Figure 2 this is the jump in risk from

the broken line (fundamental equilibrium) to the solid like (sunspot-like equilib-

rium). At the time of the panic the fundamental itself does not change. Rather,

it suddenly takes on the additional role of a variable around which beliefs about

risk are coordinated. As we can see from Figure 2, the increase in risk can be very

large, particularly when the fundamental is either very weak or very strong.

We consider the latter case less realistic in practice as sharp increases in risk

usually happen when the market is concerned about a bad fundamental. It would

be more realistic to assume that the switching probabilities are a function of the

fundamental itself, with the probability of a switch to the high risk state being

larger when the fundamental is weaker. That would avoid a large risk panic when

the fundamental is strong. It would also avoid the strange result of a drop in equity

prices when the fundamental improves, which happens in Figure 2 for positive

values of AH,t. We nonetheless abstract from this element of realism here in order

to maintain analytic tractability. We not only keep p1 and p2 fixed, but only

consider risk panics for the case where they are infinitesimally close to 1.

Figure 2 shows that the drop in the world equity price can be very large when

the panic happens at a time that the fundamental is weak. This is also illustrated

in Figure 3, which shows what happens to the world equity price and risk as a

result of the panic that happens at the time that the macro fundamental (Home

dividend) is at its weakest, i.e., is equal to −0.1.17 We assume that in period 6

the world economy switches to the high risk state, where it stays until period 10.

Before and after that we are in the low risk state. The panic leads to a 48% drop

in the world equity price. This is caused by an increase in world equity price risk

17This value comes from the fact that εH,t = −σ = −0.01 and ρ = 0.9.

17

from 0.4% to 14%. Of course, dependent on the parameters one can get even larger

or smaller risk panics. For example, if we lower Z from 0.5 to 0.4, the panic leads

to a 61% drop in the world equity price and risk increases from 0.5% to 23%.18

5 The Impact of the Global Risk Panic on Indi-

vidual Countries

The previous section described how global asset prices could collapse because of a

risk panic. An important question is how the individual countries are affected by

the panic. This is the question that we address in this section.

5.1 Country Prices and Covariance

To look at the different price reactions, we need to determine QD,t from (19). We

will consider the following solution:

QD,t = QD + vDHAH,t + vDFAF,t + VDHA2H,t (30)

As in the previous section, we assume that only the Home dividend AH,t can

coordinate self-fulfilling shifts in risk.

To determine the parameters in (30) we take the following steps. First, we con-

jecture (30). Then we compute the expectation of QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1 and covariance

between QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1 and QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1. Substituting the result in (19), we

can solve for the 4 parameters in the conjecture (30) for QD,t. Together with QW,t

this gives the equity price of both countries: the Home and Foreign equity prices

are respectively QH,t = QW,t + (1−n)QD,t and QF,t = QW,t−nQD,t. Details of the

algebra are left to Appendix B. We first discuss the fundamental equilibrium and

then turn to sunspot-like equilibria and switching equilibria featuring risk panics.

In the fundamental equilibrium we have VDH = 0, vDH = mρ/(R − ρ) and

vDF = −mρ/(R − ρ). The expressions for the equity prices of the two countries

18While our aim here is certainly not to draw precise quantitative comparisons to the recent

crisis, we should point out that the numbers that we reported in Figure 1 for the VIX cannot be

directly compared to those reported here for risk. The VIX numbers are risk measures that are

multiplied by the square root of 12 in order to annualize them. For example, a VIX of 80 implies

that equity price risk over the next month is 23%.

18

then become

QH,t =1

R− 1

Z − ( mR

R− ρ

)2γK

WσHW

+mρ

R− ρAH,t (31)

QF,t =1

R− 1

Z − ( mR

R− ρ

)2γK

WσFW

+mρ

R− ρAF,t (32)

where σiW = cov(εi,t+1, εW,t+1), i = H,F , is the covariance between the Home

(Foreign) and world dividend innovation. The latter is defined as εW,t+1 = nεH,t+1+

(1− n)εF,t+1. It is natural to assume that σiW > 0. Two points are worth making

with regards to this fundamental equilibrium. First, the constant terms depend on

the covariance of the dividend innovation with the world dividend innovation. The

higher is this covariance, the riskier the asset and therefore the lower the price.

Second, equity prices only depend on domestic dividend innovations. Thus, there

is no contagion of shocks across countries. This is because we have shut down the

regular channels of contagion through the interest rate and wealth. Both are held

constant.

Sunspot-like equilibria can also be computed following the solution method

discussed above. Appendix B computes the values of the four unknown parameters

of the conjecture (30) forQD,t. The impact of the Foreign fundamentalAF,t remains

the same in the sunspot-like equilibrium as in the fundamental equilibrium. This

reflects the fact that the Foreign dividend only plays a pure fundamental role (by

assumption). The impact of the Home fundamental AH,t is more complex as it

coordinates beliefs about risk in the sunspot-like equilibrium.

In order to understand what drives the solution of asset prices as a function

AH,t, it is useful to consider equation (19). It equates the difference in the excess

payoff on Home and Foreign equity to the difference in their respective risk premia.

Integrating forward, and ruling out bubbles, we have

QD,t =mρ

R− ρAD,t −γK

W

∞∑i=1

1

RiEtcovt+i−1(QD,t+i + ZD,t+i, QW,t+i + ZW,t+i) (33)

This equation holds both in the fundamental and sunspot-like equilibrium. A

risk panic involves a switch from the fundamental equilibrium to the sunspot-like

equilibrium. Since AD,t does not change during the panic, the change in QD,t

19

during the panic is equal to

∆QD,t = −γKW

∞∑i=1

1

Ri∆Etcovt+i−1(QD,t+i + ZD,t+i, QW,t+i + ZW,t+i) (34)

When ∆QD,t differs from 0, the panic affects the asset prices of the two countries

differently.

Equation (34) implies that the panic affects the two countries differently to

the extent that it affects the relative riskiness of the assets differently. This in

turn depends on how it affects the covariance between the equity payoffs of the

individual countries and the global payoff. If this covariance rises more for the

Home than the Foreign country, so that the covariance between QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1

and QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1 increases, then risk increases more in the Home country and

its equity price drops more during the panic.

Write ∆cov as the change in the covariance between QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1 and

QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1 from the fundamental to the sunspot-like equilibrium. Using the

results from Appendix B, we can write this as

∆cov =Rm

R− ρ(1− ρHF )σ2(vWH − vWH)− ρm

1− ρσHW (vDH − vDH) +

[Rm

R− ρ(1− ρHF )σ2VWH −ρm

1− ρσHWVDH + (vDH − vDH)σ2VWH

]AH,t +

4ρ2σ2VWHVDHA2H,t (35)

where a bar stands for the value of the parameter in the fundamental equilibrium.

While (35) may appear a complicated expression at first, we will see that it pro-

vides insight into the various mechanisms that determine how much the individual

countries are affected by the panic.

5.2 Two Factors Determining the Impact of Global Panic

on Individual Countries

At a general level, two factors determine how much the individual countries are

affected by the crisis: (1) an indeterminacy and (2) differences in fundamental

hedging properties.

We show in Appendix B that VDH is indeterminate in the sunspot-like equi-

librium. While we know the coefficient on A2H,t for the global equity price, how

20

this average coefficient for the global price divides across the two assets is not

determinate. This indeterminacy is due to another type of self-fulfilling beliefs.

If agents believe that the Home country will be more affected by the panic, then

their beliefs will be fulfilled in equilibrium.

This can be seen from (35). If the Home equity price depends more negatively

on A2H,t, which happens when VDH < 0, then the relative risk of Home equity

during the panic depends more positively on A2H,t (recall that VWH < 0). This in

turn justifies a more negative coefficient on A2H,t in the equilibrium Home equity

price. To put it another way, when the Home equity price depends more negatively

on A2H,t in the sunspot-like equilibrium, the covariance with the world equity price

depends more positively on A2H,t.19 This increases its risk as a function of A2H,t,

which in turn justifies the more negative coefficient on A2H,t in the Home equity

price.

The second factor that determines how much the individual countries are af-

fected by the global panic is associated with the fundamental hedging properties

of the assets. An asset is a more attractive hedge against global risk when its

payoff covaries less with the global payoff. The fundamental payoff on an asset is

the payoff in the fundamental equilibrium, when there are no self-fulfilling shifts in

risk. As we have seen, the payoff in the fundamental equilibrium only depends on

the asset’s dividend. A higher covariance between the dividend of an asset and the

global payoff in the sunspot-like equilibrium implies a weaker hedge. This leads to

a larger impact of the panic.

In order to illustrate these points more precisely and obtain a better under-

standing of the role of the parameters in driving the results, we first consider the

case where the macro variables AH,t and AF,t have a large fundamental role (m is

large) and then the case where they play a small fundamental role (m close to 0).

We will argue that the latter is more realistic.

5.3 Large Fundamental Role of Macro Variables

In the case where m is much above zero, so that the macro variables have a large

fundamental role, we obtain two results. First, the impact of the indeterminacy on

19This is because the world equity price also depends negatively on A2H,t and the variance of

A2H,t+1 depends positively on A2H,t.

21

the equilibrium prices is limited. Second, the fundamental hedging properties of

the assets are such that the panic affects the Home country more than the Foreign

country.

These two results are illustrated in Figure 4 for the same parameterization as

used in Figures 2 and 3. The assumption m = 1 implies that the macro variables

play an important fundamental role. Figure 4 shows the impact of a risk panic

on the equity prices and risk of both countries. As in Figure 3, the panic is

assumed to take place when the fundamental is at its weakest (AH = −0.1). Risk

is again measured as the standard deviation of the equity price over the next period,

divided by its current price. The results are shown as a function of VDH , which is

indeterminate. All values of VDH are considered for which the Home and Foreign

equity prices are positive for all possible realizations of the state space (AH,t, AF,t).

Clearly, the Figure shows that the indeterminacy associated with VDH has very

little impact on the outcome and that the panic has a much larger impact on the

Home country.

The indeterminacy in VDH has little impact because VDH affects not only the

coefficient on the quadratic term A2H,t in the asset prices, but also the coefficient on

the linear term in AH,t. As we lower VDH below zero, the more negative quadratic

term for the Home price by itself increases the magnitude of a risk panic for the

Home country. But the coefficient on the linear term in AH,t for the Home price

will also be lower, which reduces the panic in the Home country when the Home

fundamental is weak at the time of the panic (AH,t < 0).

The lower coefficient on AH,t follows from (35). As we lower VDH below zero,

the relative risk of the Home equity depends more positively on AH,t, which lowers

the coefficient on AH,t in the Home equity price and more so the larger m. Since

the world equity price depends negatively on AH,t, a more negative quadratic term

in AH,t for the Home equity price increases the covariance between the Home

and world equity price as a linear function of AH,t.20 This increase in risk of Home

equity as a linear function of AH,t reduces the coefficient on AH,t in the equilibrium

Home equity price.

The second factor determining the extent to which the individual countries

are affected by the panic is associated with the fundamental hedging properties

20This is because cov(AH,t+1, A2H,t+1) = 2ρσ2AH,t depends positively on AH,t.

22

of the assets. This leads to a larger impact of the panic in the Home country.

The expression for ∆cov in (35) provides some understanding of these hedging

properties. Assume for now that vDH = vDH , so that the relative size of the linear

coefficients remains the same as in the fundamental equilibrium (the deviation of

vDH from vDH in equilibrium only serves to amplify the results that we are about

to describe). Then, since vWH < vWH and VWH < 0, it follows from (35) that

both the constant term and the coefficient on AH,t are negative in the expression

for ∆cov.

At AH,t = 0, the risk panic then makes the Home equity a relatively better

hedge against global risk, leading to a smaller drop in the Home equity price.

The negative linear coefficient on AH,t in ∆cov implies that the weaker the Home

fundamental at the time of the panic (the more negative AH,t), the less attractive

the Home equity as a hedge against global risk as a result of the panic. This leads

to a larger risk panic in the Home country.21 We find that unless AH,t is very close

to 0, the second effect dominates, leading to a larger panic in the Home country.

The intuition for these findings is associated with the extent to which the

dividend of the equities is a hedge against the global risk faced by the agents in

the sunspot-like equilibrium. Since vWH < 0 in the high risk equilibrium, this

reduces the relative risk of the Home equity as its dividend becomes negatively

correlated with vWHAH,t, making it a better hedge against global risk and reducing

the relative size of the panic in the Home country.

The quadratic term in the global equity price is VWHA2H,t. As VWH < 0,

the covariance of this term with the Home dividend, 2mρVWHσ2AH,t, depends

negatively on AH,t. This increases the relative risk of the Home asset when AH,t < 0

and more so the more negative AH,t. When the Home fundamental is sufficiently

weak this causes a larger drop in the Home equity price during the panic.

Not surprisingly, this difference in hedging properties becomes small when ρHF

is large. This is illustrated in Figure 5, which is the same as Figure 4 except that

ρHF is set equal to 0.99 rather than 0.5. In that case the hedging properties of

the Home and Foreign dividends are virtually identical and the panic affects the

21These results are reinforced when we take into account that they imply vDH > vDH as a

negative linear term in ∆cov implies a more positive coefficient on AH,t in the Home equity

price than the Foreign equity price. Therefore vDH > vDH , which in turn generates even more

negative coefficients in both the constant and linear terms in the expression for ∆cov.

23

covariance with the global payoff virtually the same across the two assets.

The size of the country that is the focal point for the panic does not matter

much in these results. Even if the Home country is small relative to the global

economy, it remains the case that the risk panic is much larger in the Home country.

For example, setting n = 0.1 and VDH = 0, risk increases 55% and 12% in the

Home and Foreign country respectively, while their respective equity prices drop

by 80% and 46%.

5.4 Weak Fundamental Role of Macro Variables

Next consider the case where m is close to zero. The macro variables AH,t and

AF,t then play a very limited fundamental role. This should be interpreted more

generally as the case where macro variables have limited impact on payoffs of the

assets in normal (non-panic) times. We believe this is a reasonable assumption for

various reasons. First, it is well known that observed macro variables have limited

explanatory power for asset prices outside of crisis episodes.22 Second, even when

macro variables affect the payoff directly through dividends, their overall impact

on the payoff of equity (dividend plus future equity price) is relatively small. This

is because most of the equity payoff volatility is driven by the price. Moreover, it

is well-known since the early work by Shiller (1981) that dividend volatility has

very limited explanatory power for equity price volatility.

When the macro variables have a weak fundamental role (m close to 0), the

fundamental hedging properties of the assets become very similar. The only fun-

damental difference between the assets is their dividends, which are now very little

affected by the macro variables. This by itself leads the countries to be affected

equally by the panic.

But the other factor determining the impact of the global panic on the two

countries, the indeterminacy, now plays a larger role. As can be seen from (35),

when m is small VDH only impacts relative risk through the quadratic term. There

is no longer an offset through the linear term. This is illustrated in Figure 6, which

has the same parameterization as for Figure 4 except that m = 0. The panic affects

22For equity prices the limited role of public news was first illustrated by Roll (1988). For

another asset price, the exchange rate, this disconnect from observed macro fundamentals has

received even more attention.

24

the two countries equally when VDH = 0. But the indeterminacy associated with

VDH now has a big impact on how the panic affects the two countries.

Nonetheless a good case can be made for VDH = 0 as a plausible outcome.

First, any deviation from VDH = 0 is entirely arbitrary. While it is possible for

investors to believe that the panic should affect one country more than the other,

there is no a priori reason for this to be the case as the assets are not different in

any fundamental way.

Second, and perhaps more convincing, VDH = 0 is justified based on a small

cost of reshuffling portfolios. Assume that investors from both countries can invest

in a domestic stock fund and a global stock fund. The latter has constant shares

allocated to Home and Foreign equity. When VDH = 0 and m = 0, the equity

prices of both countries will drop the same percentagewise in the panic. From the

equity market clearing conditions this implies that αH,t and αF,t remain in the same

proportion (both falling). In this case all that investors need to do is sell off the

global fund (get out of risky assets). There is no need to also change the allocation

to the domestic fund. If the panic affects countries differently, then αH,t/αF,t will

change, requiring changes in the allocation to both funds. Figure 7 illustrates the

response of equity prices and risk to a risk panic when m = VDH = 0. The panic

affects equity prices and risk in the two countries equally. This case is therefore

closely consistent with what we have seen in the data during recent crises.

5.5 On the Role of Financial Integration

How does the extent of financial integration affect the impact of a panic on the two

countries? The empirical evidence shows that the extent of cross-border financial

holdings has no measurable impact on the extent to which countries were affected

by the recent crisis. This is relatively easy to explain in our framework. Consider a

financial friction τ that reduces the excess payoff on equity from the point of view of

investors from the other country. In other words, the excess payoff rH,t+1 on Home

equity becomes rH,t+1 − τ from the perspective of Foreign investors. Similarly,

the excess payoff rF,t+1 on Foreign equity becomes rF,t+1 − τ for Home investors.

Such frictions have been introduced in many papers and are usually interpreted as

a shorthand for a wide range of possible frictions that inhibit cross-border asset

holdings. They affect the level of cross-border portfolio holdings, but they do not

25

affect the marginal trade-offs. Changes in expected payoffs still lead to the same

portfolio shifts for both Home and Foreign investors.

While a larger τ reduces cross-border asset holdings, it has no effect on the

magnitude of the global panic and how much it affects the two countries. The

friction τ only affects the constant term in the equity price solutions. For both the

fundamental and sunspot-like equilibria it changes the mean of QW by −2n(1 −n)τ/(R − 1) and the mean of QD by −(1 − 2n)τ/(R − 1). Our model therefore

does not necessarily generate any relationship between cross-border asset holdings

and the extent to which countries are affected by the panic.

More fundamentally, the debate about the role of cross-border asset holdings

is relevant when financial contagion is due to the transmission of shocks. One

can imagine that a shock in one country has a larger impact on other countries if

financial linkages are stronger. But in our model the impact of a panic on individual

countries does not occur through the transmission of shocks, so that the magnitude

of financial linkages is not a determining factor. Rather, what coordinates the panic

across countries is an event that suddenly draws attention of investors all over the

world to a weak fundamental somewhere. This weak fundamental, by becoming

a common focal point of attention by investors everywhere, leads to a widespread

self-fulfilling increase in risk perceptions.

6 Conclusion

The paper is motivated by the sharp increase in equity price risk across many coun-

tries during recent financial crises. Remarkably, the magnitude of this increase in

perceived risk is very similar across countries and is associated with a similar drop

in equity prices across many countries. Moreover, the extent of cross-border finan-

cial linkages appears to have little impact on how much countries were affected.

In addition, all of this appears to have happened without sudden large shocks to

fundamentals.

In order to shed light on this phenomenon, we have developed a theory of

risk panics that has the following features. First, there is a sharp increase in risk

and a drop in equity prices in all countries. Second, the panic does not spread

across countries through financial linkages but is rather the result of a coordinated

increase in risk perceptions all over the world due to an event that draws the

26

attention to a particularly weak macro variable somewhere in the world. Third,

the global panic is not caused by a change in any fundamental, but is rather the

result of a self-fulfilling increase in perceived risk that is coordinated by a weak

fundamental.

We have shown that the panic tends to be larger in the country whose macro

fundamental becomes the focal point of the self-fulfilling increase in risk. But when

observed macro variables have a limited impact on equity prices in normal times,

as observed in the data, we have shown that the panic can affect countries very

similarly, as seen in the recent crises. Both the spike in risk and the drop in the

equity price will then be similar.

While we have offered one explanation for the huge spike in risk associated with

equity prices, and the very similar magnitude of this panic across the world, this

topic deserves a lot more attention in future research. Not much work has been

done in macroeconomics in understanding what drives such substantial changes in

risk, let alone the common pattern across the globe in this regard. We hope that

this will change in the future, putting us in a position to have a horse race among

competing theories.

27

Appendix

A Solution World Equity Price

In this Appendix we derive the solution for the world equity price in Section 4.

Start with the conjecture (25)

QW,t = QW + vWHAH,t + vWFAF,t + VWHA2H,t (36)

Note that this also includes the fundamental equilibrium as a special case, where

VWH = 0. We need to compute the expectation and variance of QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1.

We have

QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1 =

QW + Z + (vWH + nm)AH,t+1 + (vWF + (1− n)m)AF,t+1 + VWHA2H,t+1 =

QW + Z + VWHρ2A2H,t + (vWH + nm)ρAH,t + (vWF + (1− n)m)ρAF,t +

(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)εH,t+1 + (vWF + (1− n)m)εF,t+1 + VWHε2H,t+1 (37)

It follows that

Et(QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) = (38)

QW + Z + VWHρ2A2H,t + (vWH + nm)ρAH,t + (vWF + (1− n)m)ρAF,t + VWHσ

2

and

vart(QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) =

(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)2σ2 + (vWF + (1− n)m)2σ2 +

2(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vWF + (1− n)m)ρHFσ2 + V 2

WHω2 (39)

Substituting these results into (18), we have

QW + Z + VWHρ2A2H,t + (vWH + nm)ρAH,t + (vWF + (1− n)m)ρAF,t + VWHσ

2

−RQW −RvWHAH,t −RvWFAF,t −RVWHA2H,t =

γK

W(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)

2σ2 +γK

W(vWF + (1− n)m)2σ2 +

γK

W2(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vWF + (1− n)m)ρHFσ

2 +γK

WV 2WHω

2 (40)

28

Collecting first terms proportional to A2H,t and equating coefficients on the left

and right hand side, we have

VWH(ρ2 −R) =γK

W4V 2

WHρ2σ2 (41)

This has two solutions: VWH = 0 (the fundamental equilibrium) and

VWH = − W

γK

R− ρ24ρ2σ2

(42)

Next collect terms proportional to AF,t and equate coefficients on the left and

right hand side. This gives

vWF =(1− n)mρ

R− ρ (43)

This solution is the same in the fundamental and sunspot-like equilibrium.

Next collect terms proportional to AH,t and equate coefficients on the left and

right hand sides. This gives

vWH =nmρ− 4γK

WVWHρ [nmσ2 + (vWF + (1− n)m)ρHFσ

2]

R− ρ+ 4γKWVWHρσ2

(44)

Substituting the expressions for VWH and vWF , in the fundamental equilibrium we

have

vWH =nmρ

R− ρ (45)

while in the sunspot-like equilibrium we have

vWH = − m

1− ρ

(n+

R− ρ2R− ρ ρHF (1− n)

)(46)

Finally equating the constant terms on both sides, we have

QW =1

R− 1

(Z + VWHσ

2 − γK

WV 2WHω

2 − γK

Wv′Σv

)(47)

where Σ is the variance-covariance matrix of (εH,t+1, εF,t+1)′ and v = (vWH +

nm, vWF + (1− n)m)′.

29

B Solution Equity Price Difference

From (30) we have

QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1 =

QD + (vDH +m)AH,t+1 + (vDF −m)AF,t+1 + VDHA2H,t+1 =

QD + VDHρ2A2H,t + (vDH +m)ρAH,t + (vDF −m)ρAF,t +

(vDH +m+ 2VDHρAH,t)εH,t+1 + (vDF −m)εF,t+1 + VDHε2H,t+1 (48)

It follows that

Et(QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1) = (49)

QD + VDHρ2A2H,t + (vDH +m)ρAH,t + (vDF −m)ρAF,t + VDHσ

2

and

covt(QD,t+1 + ZD,t+1, QW,t+1 + ZW,t+1) =

(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vDH +m+ 2VDHρAH,t)σ2 +

(vWF + (1− n)m)(vDF −m)σ2 + (vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vDF −m)ρHFσ2 +

(vWF + (1− n)m)(vDH +m+ 2VDHρAH,t)ρHFσ2 + VWHVDHω

2 (50)

(19) then becomes

QD + VDHρ2A2H,t + (vDH +m)ρAH,t + (vDF −m)ρAF,t + VDHσ

2

−RQD −RvDHAH,t −RvDFAF,t −RVDHA2H,t =

γK

W(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vDH +m+ 2VDHρAH,t)σ

2 +

γK

W(vWF + (1− n)m)(vDF −m)σ2 +

γK

W(vWH + nm+ 2VWHρAH,t)(vDF −m)ρHFσ

2 +

γK

W(vWF + (1− n)m)(vDH +m+ 2VDHρAH,t)ρHFσ

2 +

γK

WVWHVDHω

2 (51)

First collecting terms proportional to A2H,t, we have

VDH(ρ2 −R) = 4γK

WVWHVDHρ

2σ2 (52)

30

In the fundamental equilibrium, where VWH = 0, it follows that VDH = 0. After

substituting (42), it follows that (52) holds for all values of VDH in the sunspot-like

equilibrium. Next collecting terms proportional to AF,t, we find

vDF = − mρ

R− ρ (53)

This holds both in the fundamental and sunspot-like equilibrium.

Next collecting terms proportional to AH,t, we have

vDH =mρ− 2ργK

W(η1VDH + η2VWH)

R− ρ+ 2γKWVWHρσ2

(54)

where

η1 = (vWH + nm)σ2 + (vWF + (1− n)m)ρHFσ2 (55)

η2 = mσ2 + (vDF −m)ρHFσ2 (56)

In the fundamental equilibrium where VWH = VDH = 0, it follows that

vDH =mρ

R− ρ (57)

In the sunspot-like equilibrium vDH depends on VDH , which is indeterminate.

When VDH = 0 we have

vDH = mρ2 +R− R−ρ2

R−ρ RρHF

R(2ρ− 1)− ρ2 (58)

This uses the value for vDF in the expression for η2 and the expression for VWH .

Finally, collecting constant terms, we have

QD =1

R− 1

(VDHσ

2 − γK

WVWHVDHω

2 − γK

Wv′1Σv2

)(59)

where v1 = (vWH + nm, vWF + (1− n)m)′ and v2 = (vDH +m, vDF −m)′.

31

C Implied Volatility Indices

Country Source

Belgium Datastream

Full name: BEL 20 Volatility

Computed from: BEL 20 Index options, 1 month

Canada Montreal Exchange

Full name: MX Implied Volatility Index

Computed from: CDN S&P/TSX60 Fund, 1 month

France Datastream

Full name: CAC 40 Volatility

Computed from: CAC 40 Index options, 1 month

Germany Datastream

Full name: VDAX - NEW

Computed from: DAX Index options traded at Eurex, 1 month

India National Stock Exchange of India

Full name: India VIX

Computed from: NIFTY Index options, 1 month

Japan CSFI, University of Osaka

Full name: CSFI - VXJ

Computed from: Nikkei 225 Index options, 1 month

Mexico Mexican Derivatives Exchange

Full name: VIMEX

Computed from: IPC options traded at MexDer, 3 months

Netherlands Datastream

Full name: AEX Volatility

Computed from: AEX Index options, 1 month

South Africa Johannesburg Stock Exchange

Full name: SAVI Top40

Computed from: FTSE/JSE Top40 Index options, 3 months

South Korea Korea Exchange

Full name: VKOSPI

Computed from: KOSPI200 Index options, 1 month

Switzerland Swiss Exchange

Full name: VSMI

Computed from: SMI options traded at Eurex, 1 month

U.S.A. Datastream

Full name: CBOE - VIX

Computed from: S&P 500 index options, 1 month

32

References

[1] Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee (2004), “A Cor-

porate Balance-Sheet Approach to Currency Crises,” Journal of Economic

Theory 119, 6-30.

[2] Allen, Franklin and Douglas Gale (1994), “Limited Market Participation and

Volatility of Asset Prices,” American Economic Review 84, 933-955.

[3] Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale (2000), ”Financial Contagion,” Journal of

Political Economy 108, 1-33.

[4] Aoki, M. (1981), Dynamics Analysis of Open Economies, Academic Press,

New York.

[5] Bacchetta, Philippe and Eric van Wincoop (2006), “Can Information Hetero-

geneity Explain the Exchange Rate Determination Puzzle?,” American Eco-

nomic Review 96, 552-576.

[6] Bacchetta, Philippe, Cedric Tille, and Eric van Wincoop (2010), “Self-

fulfilling Risk Panics,” NBER Working Paper No. 16159.

[7] Beirne, John, Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Marianne Schulze-Ghattas, and

Nicola Spagnolo (2009), ”Volatility Spillovers and Contagion from Mature

to Emerging Stock Markets,” European Central Bank Working Paper No.

1113.

[8] Bekaert, Geert and Campbell R. Harvey (1995), ”Time-Varying World Market

Integration,” Journal of Finance 50, 403-444.

[9] Calvo, Guillermo A. (1999), ”Contagion in Emerging Markets: When Wall

Street Is a Carrier,” mimeo.

[10] Calvo, Guillermo A. and Enrique G. Mendoza (2000), ”Rational Contagion

and the Globalization of Securities Markets,” Journal of International Eco-

nomics 51, 79-113.

[11] Dedola, Luca and Giovanni Lombardo (2010), ”Financial Frictions, Financial

Integration and the International Propagation of Shocks,” mimeo.

[12] Devereux, M.B. and J. Yetman (2010), “Financial Deleveraging and the In-

ternational Transmission of Shocks,” NBER Working Paper No. 16226.

33

[13] Diebold, Francis X. and Kamil Yilmaz (2009), Measuring Financial Asset

Return and Volatility Spillovers, with Application to Global Equity Markets,”

The Economic Journal 119, 158—171.

[14] Dornbusch, Rudiger, Yung Chul Park, and Stijn Claessens (2000), ”Contagion:

Understanding How It Spreads,” The World Bank Research Observer 15, 177-

97.

[15] Edwards, Sebastian and Raul Susmel (2001), ”Volatility Dependence, and

Contagion in Emerging Equity Markets,” Journal of Development Economics

66(2), 505-32.

[16] Fostel, Ana and John Geanakoplos (2008), “Leverage Cycles and the Anxious

Economy,” American Economic Review 98(4), 1211-1244.

[17] Giannone, Domenico, Michele Lenza, and Lucrezia Reichlin (2010) “Market

Freedom and the Global Recession,” ECARES working paper 2010-020.

[18] Gromb, Denis and Dimitri Vayanos (2002), “Equilibrium and Welfare in Mar-

kets with Financially Constrained Arbitrageurs,” Journal of Financial Eco-

nomics 66, 361-407.

[19] Imbs, Jean (2010), ”The First Global Recession in Decades,” mimeo.

[20] Jeanne, Olivier and Andrew K. Rose (2002), “Noise Trading and Exchange

Rate Regimes,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 77, 537-569.

[21] Kamin, Steven B. and Laurie Pounder (2010), ”How Did a Domestic Housing

Slump Turn into a Global Financial Crisis?” Federal Reserve Board Interna-

tional Finance Discussion Paper No. 994.

[22] Karolyi, G. Andrew (2003), ”Does International Financial Contagion Really

Exist?” International Finance 6:2, 179—199.

[23] King, Mervin, Enrique Sentana and Sushil Wadhwani (1994), “Volatility and

Links between National Stock Markets,” Econometrica 62 (4), 901-933.

[24] King, Mervin and Sushil Wadhwani (1990), “Transmission of Volatility be-

tween Stock Markets,” Review of Financial Studies 3(1), 5-33.

[25] Krugman, Paul (2008), ”The International Finance Multiplier,” mimeo.

[26] Kyle, Albert S. and Wei Xiong (2001), “Contagion as a Wealth Effect,” The

Journal of Finance 56(4), 1401-1440.

34

[27] Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti (2010) “The Cross-Country

Incidence of the Global Crisis,” IMF Economic Review 58(2), forthcoming.

[28] Manuelli, Rodolfo E. and James Peck (1992), “Sunspot-like Effects of Random

Endowments,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 16, 193-206.

[29] Mendoza, Enrique and Vincenzo Quadrini (2010), ”Financial Globalization,

Financial Crises and Contagion,” Journal of Monetary Economics, forthcom-

ing.

[30] Masson, Paul (1999), ”Contagion: Macroeconomic Models with Multiple

Equilibria,” Journal of International Money and Finance 18, 587—602.

[31] Obstfeld, Maurice (1986), ’Rational and self-fulfilling balance-of-payments

crises,’ American Economic Review 76, 72-81.

[32] Pagano, Marco (1989), “Endogenous Market Thinness and Stock Price

Volatility,” Review of Economic Studies 56, 269-288.

[33] Pavlova, Anna and Roberto Rigobon (2008), “The Role of Portfolio Con-

straints in the International Propagation of Shocks,” Review of Economic

Studies 75, 1215-1256.

[34] Roll, Richard (1988), “R2,” Journal of Finance 43 (2), 541-566.

[35] Rose, Andrew and Mark Spiegel (2010), “The Causes and Consequences of

the 2008 Crisis: International Linkages and American Exposure,” Pacific Eco-

nomic Review 15, 340-363.

[36] Schinasi, Garry J. and R. Todd Smith (2000), “Portfolio Diversification,

Leverage, and Financial Contagion,” IMF Staff Papers 47, 159-176.

[37] Shiller, Robert J. (1981), “Do Stock Prices Move Too Much to be Justified

by Subsequent Changes in Dividends?,” American Economic Review 71(3),

421-436.

[38] Soriano, Pilar and Francisco Climent (2006), “Volatility Transmission Models:

A Survey,” Revista de Economıa Financiera, N.10, 32-81.

[39] Walker, Todd B. and Charles H. Whiteman (2007), “Multiple Equilibria in a

Simple Asset Pricing Model, ” Economic Letters 97(3), 191-196.

35

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

Source: Datastream and local stock markets. See Figure 1 for a description.

Figure 1: Implied Volatility Indices

010

203040

506070

8090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-100

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

0

1020

3040

5060

7080

90

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-100

102030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-100

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

010

2030405060708090

Jan-07 Jan-08 Jan-09 Jan-10

U.S.A. JAPAN CANADAGERMANY

FRANCE SWITZERLAND NETHERLANDSBELGIUM

INDIA SOUTH KOREA SOUTH AFRICAMEXICO

0

3

6

9

12

15

-0.1 -0.08 -0.06 -0.04 -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1

Figure 2 World Equity Price and Risk*

0

5

10

15

20

25

-0.1 -0.08 -0.06 -0.04 -0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1

1;1/;5.0;03.1;1;9.0;5.0;01.0;5.0 ========= mWKnRZ HF γρρσ*

AH,t AH,t

solid = sunspot-like equilibrium; broken = fundamental equilibrium

World Equity Price Risk

0

4

8

12

16

20

1 4 7 10 13

Figure 3 Global Risk Panic*

* Same parameterization as Figure 2. Risk panic occurs at AH,t=-0.1.

time

World Equity Price Risk

0

5

10

15

20

1 4 7 10 13time

0

20

40

60

80

-700 -600 -500 -400 -300 -200 -100 0 100

Figure 4 Impact Risk Panic Across Countries—Role of VDH *

% Drop Equity prices During Panic Increase in Risk During Panic

0

10

20

30

40

-700 -600 -500 -400 -300 -200 -100 0 100

* The parameterization is the same as in Figure 2. The risk panic occurs at AH,t=-0.1.

HomeHome

Foreign

Foreign

VDH VDH

0

20

40

60

80

-300 -200 -100 0 100 200

Figure 5 Impact Risk Panic Across Countries— =0.99*

% Drop Equity prices During Panic Increase in Risk During Panic

0

10

20

30

40

-300 -200 -100 0 100 200

* Other than ρHF=0.99, the parameterization is the same as in Figure 2. The risk panic occurs at AH,t=-0.1.

Home

HomeForeign

Foreign

VDH VDH

HFρ

0

20

40

60

80

-1100 -900 -700 -500 -300 -100 100 300 500 700 900 1100

Figure 6 Impact Risk Panic Across Countries—m=0*

% Drop Equity prices During Panic Increase in Risk During Panic

0

10

20

30

40

-1100 -900 -700 -500 -300 -100 100 300 500 700 900 1100

* Other than m=0 the parameterization is the same as in Figure 2. The risk panic occurs at AH,t=-0.1.

HomeHome

Foreign

Foreign

VDH VDH

0

4

8

12

16

20

1 4 7 10 13

Figure 7 Impact Risk Panic Across Countries--m=0 and VDH=0

time

Home Equity Price

Home Equity Price Risk

0

5

10

15

20

25

1 4 7 10 13

time

0

4

8

12

16

20

1 4 7 10 13

Foreign Equity Price

0

5

10

15

20

25

1 4 7 10 13

timetime

Foreign Equity Price Risk