51
Title, Authors & Contact Information, Date, Keywords Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance Robert J. Franzese, Jr. ([email protected] ) * Associate Professor of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor Room 4246 I.S.R. P.O. Box 1248 Ann Arbor, MI 48105 1-734-936-1850 Jude C. Hays ([email protected] ) * Assistant Professor of Political Science, University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign 361 Lincoln Hall 702 South Wright Urbana, IL 61801 1-217-244-5615 26 November 2007 [Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies, 40 th Anniversary Issue: “Frontiers of Comparative Politics, March/April 2008.] KEYWORDS : Interdependence, Spatial Econometrics, Spatio-Temporal-Lag Model, Globalization, Tax Competition, Diffusion, Galton’s Problem

Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Title, Authors & Contact Information, Date, Keywords

Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance

Robert J. Franzese, Jr. ([email protected])* Associate Professor of Political Science, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor

Room 4246 I.S.R.

P.O. Box 1248 Ann Arbor, MI 48105

1-734-936-1850

Jude C. Hays ([email protected])*

Assistant Professor of Political Science, University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign

361 Lincoln Hall 702 South Wright Urbana, IL 61801

1-217-244-5615

26 November 2007

[Forthcoming in Comparative Political Studies, 40th Anniversary Issue: “Frontiers of Comparative Politics, March/April 2008.]

KEYWORDS: Interdependence, Spatial Econometrics, Spatio-Temporal-Lag Model, Globalization,

Tax Competition, Diffusion, Galton’s Problem

Page 2: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Abstract

Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance

Robert J. Franzese, Jr.

Jude C. Hays

ABSTRACT: Interdependence is ubiquitous, and often central, across comparative politics. In

comparative political economy, for example, globalization and rising capital mobility imply tax

competition that suggests the fiscal policies of one country must depend crucially upon those of

other countries with which it competes for capital. This paper shows this theoretically and, more

generally, how any situation involving externalities from one unit’s actions on others’ implies

interdependence. Positive/negative externalities induce negative/positive interdependence, which

spurs competitive-races/free-riding, with corresponding early/late-mover advantages, and so

strategic rush-to-act/delay-and-inaction. We show next how to model such interdependent processes

empirically, that not doing so risks severe omitted-variable biases that erroneously favor domestic

and exogenous-external accounts over interdependence but that doing so naïvely risks simultaneity

biases with the opposite substantive implications. Then we discuss how to estimate properly

specified interdependence models with spatial lags by maximum likelihood and, finally, how to

interpret and present the resulting estimated spatio-temporally dynamic effects, response paths, and

long-run steady-states, with their associated standard errors. We illustrate all this by replicating a

noteworthy earlier, non-spatial, study of capital-tax competition. Web appendices contain further

technical details, literature survey, data, statistical-software code, and spreadsheet templates for

conducting all estimation and calculation procedures.

Page 3: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 1 of 28

Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory, Empirics, Substance

I. The Broad Substantive Range of Spatial Interdependence

Until recently, empirical analyses of spatial interdependence (or diffusion1) in the social sciences

remained largely confined to specialized areas of applied economics (e.g., urban/regional, real-

estate, environmental) and sociology (i.e., network analysis). However, social-scientific interest in

and applications of spatial modeling have burgeoned lately, due partly to advances in theory that

imply interdependence and in methodology to address it; partly to global substantive developments

that have raised perception of and attention to interconnectivity, at all levels, from micro/personal to

macro/international; and partly to advances in technology for obtaining and working with spatial

data. In comparative politics too, spatial analyses are increasingly common, a welcome development

as many of the phenomena comparativists study entail substantively crucial spatial interdependence.2

Perhaps the most-extensive classical and current interest in spatial interdependence surrounds

intergovernmental diffusion of policy and/or institutions. The study of policy-innovation diffusion

among U.S. States, in particular, boasts deep roots, much current interest, and sustained attention

between.3 Similar policy-learning mechanisms underlie some comparative studies of diffusion,4 but

perhaps the closer parallel in comparative politics is institutional/regime diffusion, interest in which

is likewise long-standing and recently much invigorated. Dahl’s (1971) Polyarchy, for instance,

implicitly references international dependence among his eight causes of democracy. Starr’s (1991)

“Democratic Dominoes” and Huntington’s (1991) Third Wave give it central billing. Beissinger

(2007) and Bunce & Wolchik (2006, 2007) similarly stress contagion of East European communist

collapses and democratic transitions, as do Hagopian & Mainwaring (2005) and colleagues regarding

Latin American cycles. O’Loughlin et al. (1998), Brinks & Coppedge (2006), and Gleditsch & Ward

(2006, 2007) give actual empirical estimates of the extent, paths, or patterns of democratic diffusion;

and Kelejian et al. 2007 offer general theoretical treatment of institutional diffusion.

The substantive range of important spatial-interdependence effects extends well beyond inter-

Page 4: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 2 of 28

governmental diffusion, however, spanning the substance of comparative politics. Inside democratic

legislatures, representatives’ votes depend on others’ (expected) votes (Lacombe & Shaughnessy

2005), and, in electoral studies, citizens’ votes,5 election outcomes,6 or candidate qualities, strategies,

or contributions7 in some contests depend on those in others. Outside legislative and electoral arenas,

the ignition and/or outcomes of coups (Li & Thompson 1975), riots (Govea & West 1981), civil

wars8 or revolutions (Brinks & Coppedge 2006) in one unit depend on those in others. In micro-

behavioral work, too, much of the surging interest in contextual/neighborhood effects surrounds

effects on respondents’ behaviors or opinions of aggregates of others’ (e.g., those of the respondent’s

community or social network).9 Interdependence in social-movements,10 national identity (Lin et al.

2006), and right-wing extremism (Rydgren 2005) has also gained attention. In comparative political

economy, too, interdependence is often substantively large and central. Simmons & Elkins (2004),

e.g., stress cross-national diffusion as the main force behind recent economic liberalizations, as do

many others.11 Even more broadly, globalization, i.e., international economic integration, arguably

today’s most-notable (and indisputably its most-noted) political-economic phenomenon,12 implies

strategic (or nonstrategic) interdependence of domestic politics, policymakers, and policies. Studies

exploring such globalization-induced interdependencies are beyond rife.13

In this paper, we first introduce the theory and substance of interdependence, (1) emphasizing the

multifarious mechanisms by which it arises across the political and social sciences, (2) offering a

generic theoretical model establishing the rich and interesting logical connections from externalities

to interdependence, and (3) introducing globalization and tax-competition as an important, specific

substantive context in which interdependence figures prominently. We next (1) address the severe

empirical challenges in effectively and correctly distinguishing interdependence from other potential

sources of spatial correlation, (2) show how to specify and estimate empirical models that can make

such distinctions, and (3) show how to interpret and present effectively the results of such models.

Lastly, we illustrate all this specifically in the context of globalization, international tax-competition,

Page 5: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 3 of 28

and domestic policymaking autonomy, thus completing the paper’s subtitular cycle in proceeding

from the substance, to the theory, to the empirical specification and estimation, and back to the

substantive interpretation and presentation of spatial interdependence in comparative politics.

II. The Myriad Mechanisms, a General Theoretical Model, and an Example Substantive Context

Throughout comparative politics, spatial interdependence is ubiquitous and often quite central.

As Tobler’s First Law of Geography (Waldo Tobler: 1930-) aptly sums: “Everything is related to

everything else, but near things are more related than distant things.” What’s more, as Beck et al.’s

(2006) pithy title stresses: “Space is More than Geography.” That is, the substantive content of the

proximity in Tobler’s Law, and so the pathways along which interdependence among units may

operate, extend well beyond simple physical distance and bordering (as several of the examples

above illustrate). Elkins & Simmons (2005) and Simmons et al. (2006), for example, define and

discuss four mechanisms by which international diffusion may arise. Coercion, which may be direct

or indirect and hard (force) or soft (suasion), encompasses a generally vertical pathway by which the

powerful induce actions among the weaker. Competition refers to interdependence stemming from

economic pressures that the actions of each unit place upon others as competition with, substitutes

for, or complements to it. Learning entails situations where actors learn, in rational-Bayesian or

some other fashion, something from others’ actions about qualities of their own alternative actions.14

Emulation, finally, is ritualistic (i.e., not coerced or responsive to competition or learning) following

or doing oppositely of others (e.g., leaders, co-ethnics, co-partisans). To these, we would add a fifth

channel, migration, wherein some components of some units directly enter other units, the most

obvious examples being disease contagion or human im-/emigration, which will tend to generate a

direct, mechanical interdependence in addition to strategic or idea-dissemination.

More generally, following Brueckner (2003), we can show that strategic interdependence arises

whenever some unit(s)’s actions affect the marginal utility of alternative actions for some other(s).

Consider two units (i,j) who derive indirect utilities, (Wi,Wj), from their alternative actions. Due to

Page 6: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 4 of 28

externalities, i’s utility depends on its policy and that of j. For example, imagine two countries with

homogenous populations regarding their, say, economic and environmental preferences. Due to

environmental externalities (those surrounding pollution) and economic ones (those surrounding the

costs of environmental regulations), domestic welfare (or the net political-economic benefits/utilities

to policymakers) in each country will depend on both countries’ policies, (pi,pj):

( , ) ; ( , )i i j ji j j iW W p p W W p p≡ ≡ (1).

When country i chooses its policy, pi, to maximize its own welfare, this alters the optimal policy in

country j, and vice versa. For example, as i implements more-effective anti-pollution policy, the

need for effective anti-pollution policy in j declines due to environmental spillovers. We can express

such strategic interdependence between countries i and j with a pair of best-response functions,

giving i’s optimal policies, pi*, as a function of j’s chosen policies, pj, and vice versa:15

i j

* *p pArgmax ( , ) ( ) ; Argmax ( , ) ( )i i j j

i i j j j j i ip W p p R p p W p p R p≡ ≡ ≡ ≡ (2).

The slopes of these best-response functions, Ri(pj) and Rj(pi), indicate whether actions by i induce

j to move in the same direction, in which case we call the actions of i and j strategic complements, or

in the opposite direction, in which case they are strategic substitutes. For example, anti-pollution

policies are strategic substitutes in terms of their environmental effects as described above. These

best-response functions’ slopes depend on the following ratios of second cross-partial derivatives:

**

/ ; /i j i i j i i i

ji i j jip p p p p p p p

j i

pp W W W Wp p

∂∂ = − = −∂ ∂

(3).

If governments maximize, the second-order conditions assure that (3)’s denominators are negative,

so the reaction-function slopes depend directly on the signs of the second cross-partial derivatives in

the numerators. If , 0i j

i jp pW > , that is, if policies are strategic complements, reaction functions slope

upward. In the economic costs of anti-pollution regulation, for example, tighter regulation in i lowers

the costs of regulation in competitors j, and so spurs j to tighten regulation too. (See Figure 1 as an

Page 7: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 5 of 28

example.) If , 0i j

i jp pW < , policies are strategic substitutes, so reaction functions slope downward, as

noted with regard to the environmental benefits of anti-pollution regulation above. If , 0i j

i jp pW = ,

strategic interdependence does not materialize, and best-response functions are flat.

[Figure 1 Here]

Generally speaking, then, positive externalities induce strategic-substitute relations, and policies

will move in opposite directions as free-rider dynamics obtain. Franzese & Hays (2006b) argue and

find such free-riding dynamics in EU active-labor-market policies, for instance. Notice, furthermore,

that free-rider advantages also confer late-mover advantages, and so war-of-attrition (strategic delay

or inaction) dynamics are likely. Conversely, negative externalities create strategic complementarity,

with policies moving in the same direction. Tax competition has these features. Tax cuts in one unit

have negative externalities for competitors, pushing them to cut taxes in response. These situations

advantage early movers, so competitive races can unfold.16 Earlier movers also reap disproportionate

benefits in the contexts of competitive currency-devaluations or trade-barriers. Thus, positive and

negative externalities induce strategic-complement and -substitute relations, respectively, which spur

competitive-races and free-riding, respectively, with their corresponding early- and late-mover

advantages, and so strategic rush to go first on the one hand and delays and inaction on the other.

In this frame, globalization, specifically capital mobility, which example we elaborate next and

(re-)analyze empirically below, creates strategic policy-interdependence because it heightens cross-

border negative externalities in capital-tax policy. If this rising sensitivity steepens positively sloped

reaction-functions, competitive tax-cut races ensue. In theory, by extension, such inter-jurisdictional

competition for capital, which intensifies as capital grows more-liquid and -mobile across borders,

undermines the tax-policy autonomy of individual states, pushing tax rates to converge downward,

especially those levied on more-mobile assets. Indeed, many scholars of domestic or international

fiscal-competition (e.g., Zodrow & Mieszkowski 1986; Wilson 1986, 1999; Wildasin 1989; Oates

Page 8: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 6 of 28

2001) expect intense such competition to unleash nearly unmitigated races to some (ill-defined: see

note 16 and below) bottom. Scholarly and casual observers alike see the striking post-1970s rise in

international capital-mobility and steady postwar increase in trade integration as forcing welfare- and

tax-state retrenchment and shifting tax-burden incidence from relatively mobile bases (capital,

especially finance) toward more immobile (labor, especially less-flexibly-specialized labor).17 Rising

portfolio- and fixed-capital-market integration, in this view, sharpen capital’s threat against domestic

governments to flee perceived excessive and inefficient welfare and tax systems.

Several recent studies of tax policy over this period challenge these claims. Quinn (1997), Swank

(1998, 2002), Swank & Steinmo (2002), Garrett & Mitchell (2001), and others find international

economic integration not to have constrained governments’ fiscal policies much. Explanations for

this begin by noting that other national differences also heavily affect investment-location decisions,

affording governments maneuvering room. Hines (1999), for instance, finds firms consider final-

market proximity, intermediate-supply availability, commercial, regulatory, and other policies, and

labor-market institutions, among many other factors. Likewise, governments’ tax policies respond to

more than just competition for capital. For example, Swank (2002) finds corporate and capital tax-

rates depend on macroeconomic growth and inflation, funding requirements of programmatic

outlays, and partisan politics. Controlling for these domestic factors, he finds little relation of

taxation to capital mobility, although including spatial lags to reflect tax-policy interdependence as

in our re-analyses below and his own subsequent work (e.g., 2006) alters that conclusion. Even so,

many studies find domestic political-economic factors affect fiscal policy at least as strongly as do

external or globalization-related factors. Our empirical re-analysis returns to this question.

On closer analysis, these recent challenges to simplistic globalization-induces-welfare/tax-state-

retrenchment views have at least four distinct bases. Garrett (1998) argues that certain combinations

of left-government associated policies and labor-market coordination can be as or more efficient than

neoliberal state-minimalism and conservative government. Capital, he argues, would not flee such

Page 9: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 7 of 28

efficient combinations. Boix (1998) argues that public human- and physical-capital investment-

strategies comprise an alternative to neoliberal minimalism that is sufficiently efficient economically

to retain capital and politically effective enough to sustain left electoral-competitiveness. Soskice,

Hall, and colleagues (2001) argue that complex national networks of political-economic institutions

confer sectoral comparative advantages. As Franzese & Mosher (2002) elaborate, this implies capital

mobility and trade integration would (if international tax-competition remains sufficiently muted: see

below) favor institutional specialization: persistent welfare/tax-system variation or even divergence,

not convergence or global retrenchment. These three views, plus a fourth stressing globalization-

stoked perceptions of economic insecurity that spur welfare-state demand (Rodrik 1997, Scheve &

Slaughter 2004), fundamentally question whether globalization creates net pressures to retreat from

welfare/tax-state commitments (or at least whether all aspects of globalization do so, so strongly).

In a fifth line of counterargument, Swank (2002) contends that the institutional structures of the

polity and the welfare system itself shape the domestic policy-response to integration. He neither

fundamentally challenges the claimed exclusively superior macroeconomic efficiency of neoliberal

minimalism nor stresses the demand-spurring effects of globalization-stoked economic insecurities.

Rather, he pushes the primacy of domestic political conditions—the policymaking access, cohesion

and organization, and relative power of contending pro- and anti-welfare/tax interests—in shaping

the direction and magnitude of welfare/tax-policy reactions to economic integration. Specifically, he

finds inclusive electoral institutions, social-corporatist interest-representation and policymaking,

centralized political-authority, and universal welfare-systems favor pro-welfare interests in the

domestic political struggle over policy responses to integration. Capital mobility and globalization,

meanwhile, further welfare/tax-state largesse in previously generous states and retrenchment in tight

ones. That is, Swank suggests divergence for domestic reasons not convergence for external or

interdependent ones.18 Basinger & Hallerberg (2004) take the next step. If “countries with higher

political costs are less likely to enact reforms, [and this] reduces competing countries’ incentives to

Page 10: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 8 of 28

reform regardless of their own political costs” (2004:261). The magnitude of the tax-competition

pressures that economic integration places upon one government’s fiscal policies depends upon its

competitors’ policy choices, which is exactly the strategic interdependence we emphasize here.

Such critiques also highlight that the bottom toward which globalization and capital mobility

may push tax-competing states need not be neoliberal minimalism. Insofar as alternative political-

economic advantages or constraints allow or force some states to retain high taxes, the competitive

pressures on all states diminish. The more integrated and important are the domestically advantaged

or constrained states, the more the pressures diminish. Furthermore, if, as Franzese & Mosher (2002)

suggest, national economic-policy differences help shape comparative advantages, then both trade

and global fixed-capital integration would enhance economic pressures for specialization:

divergence, not convergence. From this view, international liquid-capital mobility alone, through the

tax-competition it engenders, induces whatever competitive races may occur.19 Finally, as Hays

(2003) and Basinger & Hallerberg (2004) stress, such races need not be to some bottom at all; rather,

the race’s competitiveness and its destination depend on the constellation of domestic political-

economic conditions present in, and the economic integration of, the international system.

Thus, international tax- and fiscal-policy competition arguments, in any of their conventional

forms and throughout each of these critiques, imply cross-national (i.e., spatial) interdependence in

fiscal policymaking. Whatever pressures on domestic policymaking may derive from rising capital

mobility, their nature and magnitude will depend on the constellation of tax (and broader economic)

systems with which the domestic unit competes. As we have shown, race-to-the-bottom dynamics

may occur when policies are strategic complements, that is, when policy changes in one unit create

incentives for others to adopt similar changes. For example, cuts in capital taxes or costly labor,

environmental, or other regulatory standards in one unit increase the costs to others of maintaining

high taxes and regulatory standards, inducing them follow suit. By contrast, free-riding occurs when

policies are strategic substitutes, that is, when policy changes in one unit create incentives for others

Page 11: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 9 of 28

to adopt change in the opposite direction. For example, an increase in defense expenditures in one

country lowers the marginal security benefit from defense spending in its military allies, creating an

incentive for them to free ride (e.g., Redoano 2003). We gave a general theoretical formulation of

interdependence in these terms above, following Brueckner (2003); a web appendix follows Persson

& Tabellini (2000:ch.12) to elaborate formally how tax competition specifically implies spatial

interdependence. The model shows how domestic policymakers’ optimal capital-tax-rates, τk, depend

not only on their own tax-policy orientation, captured in the model by their labor-endowment, eP, but

also on foreign capital-tax-rates, τk*, (and so on foreign endowments, eP*). That is, the model yields

best-response functions in the specific forms τk=T(eP,τk*) and τk*=T*(eP*,τk) for domestic and foreign

policymakers, respectively. Figure 1 graphs those assuming positive slopes.20 The comparative-static

shows an increase in the domestic policymaker’s labor-endowment (a leftward shift), which shifts

the domestic function outward and so raises equilibrium capital-tax rates in both countries.

Although formal tax-competition models like this one, or Hays (2003), or Basinger & Hallerberg

(2004), unambiguously demonstrate the strategic spatial-interdependence of capital taxes, as do the

alternative arguments reviewed above, not all tax/welfare-state retrenchment arguments necessarily

involve tax-competition. In Iversen & Cusack (2000), for example, structural labor-force changes,

specifically deindustrialization, are the main force pushing welfare/tax-state retrenchment. Pierson’s

(1994) account emphasizes path dependence, i.e., the accumulation and entrenchment of interests (or

their absence) behind welfare-state policies and institutions (technically: state, not path, dependence:

Page 2006). Cameron (1978), Rodrik (1997), and Scheve & Slaughter (2004) stress instead demand

for social policies arising from domestic interests experiencing increased economic exposure.

Such forces—labor-force structural-change, domestic-interest entrenchment and/or change—may

be related to, or even partly caused by, aspects of globalization, but, ultimately, these are domestic-

factor explanations or arguments about exogenous external trends. Therefore, by themselves they do

not imply any of the strategic interdependence among policy choices that tax-competition theories,

Page 12: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 10 of 28

instead, emphasize. We term approaches that combine these to reflect domestic factors, exogenous-

external factors, and context-conditional responses to exogenous-external conditions on one hand

and international interdependence on the other Comparative-and-International Political-Economy

(C&IPE). We will (re-)analyze two such C&IPE empirical models in the globalization and capital-

tax-competition context below. First, though, we must explain the severe empirical difficulties in

accurately estimating and distinguishing these alternative components of C&IPE models, and then

discuss some methodological approaches that may surmount these difficulties.

III. Empirical-Methodological Challenges of Spatial Interdependence

We begin by distinguishing four broad approaches in comparative politics to explaining cross-

unit variation and offering a generic empirical model that represents each. One approach prioritizes

unit-level (individual, domestic) factors, ignoring contextual effects and interdependence processes.

A second grants key roles to external/contextual shocks/conditions. In a third, a unit’s responses to

exogenous-external conditions may depend on that unit’s characteristics, and, vice versa, the effects

of unit-level characteristics may depend on context, but with context remaining exogenously external

to units. In these last two forms, exogenous-external conditions affect units’ outcomes (commonly or

context-conditionally), but units’ outcomes do not directly affect other units’ outcomes. Thus, no

reverberation occurs. In truly interdependent processes, contrarily, outcomes in some units directly

affect other units’ outcomes, implying feedback. A country may respond to an exogenous domestic

or external shock by cutting capital-taxes (unit- or contextual-level), and its response to external

shocks may depend on domestic factors (context-conditional), but its response may further depend

on what competitors do and, conversely, its own response may affect other policymakers’ choices

(interdependence). Analogously, German and French respondents’ opinions might correlate because

individual characteristics (unit-level) correlate spatially, or because political-economic conditions

correlate regionally (exogenous-external context). Respondents’ opinions may react to common

regional stimuli differently depending on their individual characteristics (context-conditional). Yet

Page 13: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 11 of 28

opinions may also correlate regionally because each respondent’s opinion depends on others’

opinions, for instance: those of “neighbors” or other regional residents (interdependence). Notice this

important implication of the concluding phrases of each example: in interdependent processes,

outcomes (i.e., dependent or left-hand-side variables, yi, or components thereof, iy or iε ) in some

units are among the explanators (right-hand-side or “independent” variables) of outcomes in others.

A central challenge for empirical researchers, known as Galton’s Problem, is the great difficulty

distinguishing common shocks (correlated responses to correlated unit-level, contextual, or context-

conditional factors) and interdependence. As elaborated later, on one hand, ignoring or inadequately

modeling interdependence processes leads analysts to exaggerate the importance of common shocks,

privileging contextual/exogenous-external or unit-level/domestic-factor accounts. On the other hand,

if the inherent simultaneity of interdependence is insufficiently redressed, then analysts will mis-

estimate (usually overestimate) the strength of interdependence at the expense of unit-level, external,

or context-conditional factors, especially insofar as these common shocks are inadequately modeled.

We begin with a strictly unit-level model of a single outcome. In closed-polity/economy CP/CPE

approaches, for instance, domestic political-economic institutions (e.g., electoral systems or central-

bank autonomy), structures (e.g., cleavages or economic-industrial structures), and conditions (e.g.,

electoral competitiveness or business cycles) are the paramount explanators of domestic outcomes.

Such domestic-primacy substantive stances imply theoretical and empirical models of this form:

it it ity ε′= +β d (4),

where yit are the outcomes to be explained and dit are the domestic or unit-level/individual factors

that explain yit. Most early empirical studies in CP/CPE, whether quantitative or qualitative, took this

form.21 CPE examples include most early work on fiscal and monetary policy (Tufte 1978, Hibbs

1987, and successors), corporatist wage-bargaining (Cameron 1984, Lange & Garrett 1985,

successors), or central-bank independence (Cukierman 1992, Alesina & Summers 1993, successors).

Page 14: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 12 of 28

As economies grew more interconnected by international trade and, later, finance, and as perhaps

polities’ geopolitical interconnectedness rose also, controls for effects of global political-economic

conditions on domestic policies and outcomes became both more important substantively and more

common in practice. At first, however, global conditions were assumed to affect all units equally and

so to induce equal responses from each unit, yielding theoretical/empirical models like this:

it d it s t ity ε′ ′= + +β d β s (5),

where st are global shocks (e.g., the oil crises), felt equally by all the sample spatial units, each of

which respond equally (each i feels identical shocks, st, and responds thereto by the same amounts,

βs).22 Examples of empirical models reflecting such stances include many post-oil-crisis political-

economy studies, including later rounds of the above literatures, wherein time-period dummies or

controls for global economic conditions or differencing of domestic from global conditions began to

appear.23 See, for example, Alvarez et al. (1991) on partisanship and corporatism; Alesina et al.

(1997) on political and/or partisan cycles; Powell & Whitten (1993) on economic voting.

Modern institutional or other context-conditional arguments stress varying unit responses to

external/contextual stimuli depending on unit-level characteristics. Domestic institutions, structures,

and conditions shape the degree and nature of domestic exposure to external shocks or of domestic

policy-outcome responses to these differently felt foreign stimuli, for example; and individuals’

education or attention levels moderate their opinion/behavioral responses to contextual factors like

the party systems in which they vote. This yields characteristic theoretical and empirical models:24

( )it d it s t sd it t ity ε′ ′ ′= + + ⊗ +β d β s β d s (6),

where the incidence, impact, or effect of contextual/external common shocks, st, on domestic/unit-

level outcomes, yit, are conditioned by domestic/unit-level contextual factors, dit, and so differ across

units.25 Much of modern CP/CPE is of this form, including the Iversen-Cusack or Cameron-Rodrik

welfare-state retrenchment arguments mentioned earlier, Garrett (1998), and Franzese (2002).26

Page 15: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 13 of 28

Analyses that recognize the interdependence of outcomes across units, contrarily, must have unit

i and unit j outcomes affecting each other, yielding this final extension of the generic model:

( )it ij jt d it s t sd it t itj i

y w yρ ε≠

′ ′ ′= + + + ⊗ +∑ β d β s β d s (7),

where yjt are the outcomes in the other (j≠i) units, which in some manner (given by ρwij) directly

affect the outcome in unit i. Note that wij reflects the relative degree of connection from j to i, and ρ

reflects the overall strength of interdependence of the outcome in i on the outcomes in the other (j≠i)

spatial units, as weighted by wij. Substantively, in the tax-competition venue, for example, the wij,

could gauge the sizes or the similarity (substitute) or complementarity of i’s and j’s economies or of

their capital or goods-and-services trade. The other right-hand-side factors reflect the model’s non-

spatial components: unit-level/domestic, contextual/exogenous-external, and context-conditional.27

Since models like (12) subsume those like (9)-(11), one might argue to begin always with (12) or

(9) and work downward or upward as data suggest/allow. However, as we summarize below (from

Franzese & Hays 2004, 2006a, 2007c, 2008ab), obtaining ‘good’ (unbiased, consistent, efficient)

estimates of coefficients and standard errors in such models and, more generally, distinguishing

interdependence processes from correlated unit-level, exogenous-external, or context-conditional

factors by any empirical method, is not straightforward. The first and prime consideration in doing

so is the relative and absolute theoretical and empirical precisions of the spatial (interdependence)

and non-spatial (common/correlated domestic/unit-level, exogenous-external, or context-conditional)

parts of the model or theory. To elaborate, the relative and absolute accuracy and power with which

the spatial-lag weights, wij, measure and offer leverage on the interdependence mechanisms actually

operating, and with which domestic, exogenous-external, and/or context-conditional components

measure and offer leverage upon the common-shocks alternatives, critically affect any attempt to

distinguish and evaluate their relative strength empirically. This is Galton’s Problem:28 intuitively,

the two mechanisms produce similar effects, so inadequacies or omissions in specifying the one tend

Page 16: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 14 of 28

to induce overestimates of the other’s importance. Secondarily, though, even with the common-

shocks and interdependence mechanisms both modeled perfectly, the spatial lags will be endogenous

(i.e., covary with residuals), so estimates of ρ will suffer simultaneity biases (as, equally, would any

qualitative attempt to distinguish interdependence from domestic or exogenous-external accounts).

Moreover, conversely to the primary omitted-variable or relative misspecification biases explained

first, these simultaneity biases tend toward over-estimating interdependence strength and inducing

biases in the opposite direction, under-estimating the domestic and/or exogenous-external.

Most of the empirical research on globalization/tax-competition and fiscal-policy autonomy or

policy diffusion analyzes panel or time-series-cross-sectional (TSCS) data (i.e., observations on units

over time). Sound empirical inference will therefore require careful modeling of temporal and spatial

interdependence.29 We have seen above that, theoretically and substantively, failure to model spatial

interdependence is a serious misspecification risking sizable omitted-variable bias, particularly in

fiscal-policymaking contexts. The easiest and most direct way to incorporate this interdependence is

with a spatio-temporal lag model, which we can write in matrix notation as:

ρ ϕ= + + +y Wy My Xβ ε (8),

Where y, the dependent variable, is an NTx1 vector of cross sections stacked by period (i.e., all N

units’ first-period observations, then their second periods, and so on to the N for period-T.30 ρ is the

previously described spatial autoregressive coefficient, and W is an NTxNT block-diagonal spatial-

weighting matrix. Wy is the spatial lag; i.e., for each observation, yit, Wy is a weighted sum of the

other units’ outcomes, yjt, with weights wij reflecting relative connectivity from j to i.31 Wy thus

straightforwardly reflects the dependence of each unit i’s outcome on unit j’s, directly following the

theoretical models and substantive arguments reviewed above. M is an NTxNT matrix with ones on

the minor diagonal (i.e., at (N+1,1), (N+2,2),…(NT,NT-N)), and zeros elsewhere, so My is just the

familiar (first-order) time-lagged dependent-variable, with φ its coefficient. The matrix X contains

NT observations on k independent variables, with β their kx1 vector of coefficients. In our generic

Page 17: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 15 of 28

models, X has columns d, s, and ⊗d s . Thus, Xβ is the non-spatial, or common-shocks, components

of domestic/unit-level, contextual/exogenous-external, and context-conditional factors. Finally, ε is

an NTx1 vector of stochastic components, assumed independent and identically distributed.32 The

spatio-temporal-lag model thus captures temporal and spatial dynamics in a familiar form. It simply

regresses the outcome, yi,t-1, on exogenous domestic/unit-level and contextual/external explanators,

xi,t, a time-lagged dependent-variable, yi,t-1, and a weighted average of the dependent variable in

other units, Σjwijyj,t, with the weights, wij, reflecting the relative connectivity from units j to unit i.

In earlier work (2004, 2006a, 2007c, 2008ab), we explored analytically and by simulation several

properties of four estimators for such models: non-spatial least-squares (i.e., regression omitting the

spatial component as is common in most extant research: OLS), spatial OLS (i.e., OLS estimation of

models like (8), which is becoming common in diffusion studies: S-OLS), instrumental variables

(e.g., spatial 2SLS or S-2SLS), and spatial maximum-likelihood (S-ML). Analytically, we can show

that the first two strategies yield biased and inconsistent estimates,33 the first due to omitted-variable

bias and the second due to the endogeneity of the spatial lag (simultaneity bias). These biases reflect

the terms of Galton’s Problem. On one hand, if researchers omit the spatial lag necessary to reflect

the actual interdependence of their data, their OLS coefficient-estimates for domestic, exogenous-

external, or context-conditional factors will suffer serious omitted-variable biases. The web appendix

gives specific formula for these biases, but the important upshot is this: Insofar as spatial lags covary

with the non-spatial regressors, which is highly likely if domestic conditions correlate spatially and

is certain for common exogenous-external shocks, OLS overestimates domestic, exogenous-external,

or context-conditional effects while ignoring spatial interdependence. Notice that this applies equally

to qualitative analyses that ignore interdependence sources of their observed phenomena. However,

OLS estimation of models including spatial lags (or qualitative observation of the spatial correlation

of outcomes across units or tracing of putative diffusion processes) entails an endogeneity— spatial

lag, Wy, covaries with residual, ε—and so simultaneity bias/inconsistency. Simply: spatial lags are

Page 18: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 16 of 28

weighted averages of outcomes in other units; they thus place some observations’ left-hand sides on

others’ right-hand sides. Simpler still, by example: Germany causes France, but France also causes

Germany: textbook simultaneity. The web appendix gives specific formulae for these simultaneity

biases. The expressions are more complicated, but their crucial upshot may be summarized thus: In

the likely common case of positive interdependence and positive covariance of spatial-lag and

exogenous regressors, for instance, one would overestimate the interdependence-strength, ρ , and

correspondingly underestimate temporal dynamics, ϕ , and domestic/external/contextual effects, β .

In sum, Galton’s Problem is that empirical analyses (by any method) that ignore interdependence

will thereby tend to overestimate the role of non-spatial factors (with the effects of those factors that

correlate most spatially being most overstated) and so privilege domestic/unit-level, exogenous-

external, and context-conditional accounts and theories. Conversely, just controlling (or considering

qualitatively) spatial-lag processes induces simultaneity biases, typically in the opposite direction,

that exaggerate the extent of interdependence and understate domestic/unit-level, exogeneous-

external, and context-conditional effects. Again, those factors that most correlate spatially with the

pattern of interdependence will tend to see the greatest induced deflation bias. These conclusions

hold as a matter of degree as well. Insofar as non-spatial components are inadequately specified and

measured relative to its interdependence components, the latter will be privileged and the former

disadvantaged, and vice versa. Thus, careful, accurate, powerful specification of W—the patterns of

relative interconnectivity—is of crucial empirical, theoretical, and substantive importance to those

interested in interdependence, obviously, but also to those for whom domestic/unit-level, exogenous-

external, or context-conditional factors are of primary interest.34 Conversely, specification of non-

spatial components is of equally crucial importance to those interested in gauging interdependence.

Our previous work also showed that the omitted-variable biases of OLS are usually worse and

often far worse than S-OLS’ simultaneity biases. Under modest interdependence strength ( ijwρ

Page 19: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 17 of 28

comfortably less than 0.3 or so), in fact, S-OLS may perform adequately (although standard-error

inaccuracy can be an issue, and in a manner for which PCSE’s do not properly compensate). Faced

with ignoring interdependence or modeling it without redressing the simultaneity, therefore, one

should generally strongly prefer the latter. However, S-OLS’ simultaneity biases do grow sizable as

interdependence strengthens, rendering the consistent estimators, like S-ML or S-2SLS, increasingly

advisable. Our analyses of estimator bias, efficiency, and standard-error accuracy found the choice

of which consistent estimator decidedly secondary, but S-ML emerges nearly weakly dominant.35

IV. Estimation of Spatial and Spatio-Temporal Models of Interdependence

We introduce estimation only very briefly and generally here.36 First, some practical notes: we

have found existing Stata code for spatial analysis unreliable and/or extremely computer-time

intensive. We recommend J.P. LeSage’s MatLab code instead. Our replication data, MatLab code,

prototype Stata code for S-ML estimation, and Excel spreadsheets for calculations and presentations

that might make useful templates, are available at www.umich.edu/~franzese/Publications.37

Next, as the preceding section concluded, the first-order issue in empirical spatial-analysis is to

model interdependence where it is appreciably present, i.e., to include spatial lags. Estimating

spatial-lag models by OLS yields biased estimates though; not too badly biased if interdependence

remains mild, but, even then, standard-error accuracy is elusive (and PCSE’s no help). A simple

alternative that may ease or even erase these problems S-OLS is to time-lag the spatial-lag (Beck et

al. 2006; Swank 2006). Insofar as a time-lagged spatial lag is pre-determined—that is, insofar as the

interdependence is not instantaneous, where instantaneous means within an observation period,

given the model—no bias arises. In other words, if spatial-interdependence processes have no effect

within an observational period, and if spatial and temporal dynamics are sufficiently well-modeled to

prevent spatial-interdependence from manifesting instantaneously due to measurement/specification

error, OLS with a time-lagged spatial-lag regressor is an effective estimation strategy.38 Following

estimation of such time-lagged spatio-temporal models with tests of whether temporal and/or spatial

Page 20: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 18 of 28

correlation remains in residuals is highly advisable. Standard Lagrange-multiplier tests for remaining

temporal correlation in regression residuals remain valid. Franzese & Hays (2004, 2008b) introduce

several tests/measures of spatial correlation, some of which are applicable to S-OLS residuals.

Unfortunately, within observational-period spatial-interdependence is almost certain in the tax-

competition context. First, the capital flows/threats that apply inter-jurisdictional pressures are all-

but-literally continuous, whereas tax-rate policymaking is far slower (annual). Second, in strategic

contexts more generally, units’ equilibrium actions depend on others’ expected actions, implying

instantaneous interdependence. Thus, even if we expect only weakly interdependent policymaking,

and even if we were willing to tolerate possibly inaccurate standard errors, capital-tax competition

would still not be a good candidate for this simplest strategy. We need one of the other estimators.

The endogeneity in S-OLS estimation is that Wy and ε covary. The instrumental-variables/two-

stage-least-squares/generalized-method-of-moments (IV/2SLS/GMM) family of estimators’ strategy

against such problems is to find instrumental variables that correlate with the endogenous regressor

but not with the residual or, restated intuitively, that affect the offending regressor, here the spatial

lag, Wy, but that do not affect the outcome, yi, except through Wy. Spatial IV/2SLS/GMM exploit

the data’s spatial structure for instruments. Unless what we call cross-spatial endogeneity, some yi

causing some xj, exists, WX, the spatial lags of the non-spatial regressors, X, are ideal instruments.

Cross-spatial endogeneity seems unlikely in many contexts (e.g., German capital-tax policy affecting

French voter-participation?), but combinations of vertical connections from yi to yj (interdependence)

and horizontal ones from yi to xi (standard reverse-causality) combine to give the offending diagonal

ones from yi to xj. Insofar as such cross-spatial endogeneity does not exist, though, our analyses

show S-2SLS yields unbiased coefficient-estimates and solid standard-error accuracy. Implementing

2SLS requires no additional code in most statistical software, so, despite its inefficiency relative to

S-ML, manually creating instruments WX to apply S-2SLS may reasonably become popular among

practitioners. However, instrumental-variable strategies like S-2SLS can become “cures worse than

Page 21: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 19 of 28

the disease” if their assumptions are violated. Fear of cross-spatial endogeneity in S-2SLS and the

slightly stronger performance of S-ML generally should therefore recommend the latter.

S-ML estimation addresses the simultaneity issues of spatial-lag models by solving the system of

equations (one per unit) to move all the endogenous variables, y and Wy, to the left-hand side, and

then maximizing the likelihood for that reduced form as usual in ML. As the web appendix formally

elaborates, conditional likelihood functions for spatio-temporal-lag models, which treat first-period

observations as predetermined, are straightforward extensions of static spatial-lag models’ likelihood

functions, which, in turn, add only one mathematically and conceptually small complication (albeit a

computationally intense one) to the likelihood functions for standard linear-normal models. We skip

the derivation here (see the web appendix and Franzese & Hays 2006a, 2007c) and simply write the

spatio-temporal-model conditional-likelihood in (Nx1) vector notation:

{ } ( ) ( ) ( )1 2 1

22, ,...,

2

1

1 1Log 1 log 2 1 log2 2

where

t t

T

t tt

t t N t N t t

f N T Tπσ ρσ

ρ ϕ−

=

′= − − + − − −

= − − −

∑y y y y I W ε ε

ε y W y I y X β (9).

With this, estimation proceeds as usual, maximizing (9) over ρ, φ, β, and σ2 for parameter estimates

and estimating their variance-covariance as minus the inverse of the second-derivative (Hessian).

We stress the feasibility of empirical spatial and spatio-temporal analysis here rather than its

great demands on specification, measurement, and sample size (more precisely: useful variation) for

four reasons. First, the preceding sections have already offered that opposite emphasis. Second, those

sections also stressed that ignoring interdependence when appreciably present is usually far worse

than imperfectly including it; they described the conditions under which simpler, inconsistent

estimators (S-OLS) may perform adequately; and they stressed that these challenges and difficulties

apply equally regardless of research mode. That is—(1) the non-ignorability of interdependence, yet

(2) the endogeneity entailed by its direct inclusion in empirical analysis, and then (3) that empirical

redress of this simultaneity bias sets high demands for specification and measurement precision and

Page 22: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 20 of 28

for much useful variation in observation—all these points apply equally to quantitative or qualitative

empirical research. The scholar of CP/CPE has little choice. We cannot ignore interdependence; it

will raise wide-ranging endogeneity; and our only recourse is therefore to model as precisely as

possible and gather as much (and as usefully varying) empirical information as possible. Third, one

increasingly popular alternative for addressing endogeneity in observational studies, propensity-

score matching, is likely inapplicable given interdependence. Its core assumption, SUTVA: stable-

unit-treatment-value assumption, means, inter alia, that no unit’s receipt, magnitude, or impact of

treatment depends on any other unit’s receipt, magnitude, or impact of treatment. That is exactly

negative the definition of interdependence, so, in a phrase: if interdependence, then not SUTVA.

Fourth, and least conclusively, in part because most preliminarily, we have begun some sensitivity

analyses of these methods (2004) and have not yet found measurement/specification error in W to be

as consequential as we had feared or as, for example, cross-spatial endogeneity does seem to be.39

V. Calculation, Interpretation, and Presentation of Spatio-Temporal Dynamics and Effects

Calculation, interpretation, and presentation of effects in empirical models with spatio-temporal

interdependence, as in any model beyond those strictly linear-additive in variables and parameters,

explicitly or implicitly,40 involve more than simply considering coefficient estimates. Coefficients do

not generally equate to effects outside that strictly linear-additive world. In empirical models with

spatio-temporal dynamics, as in those with only temporal dynamics, the coefficients on explanatory

variables give only the (often inherently unobservable) pre-dynamic impetuses to outcomes from

changes in those variables. Here we discuss the spatio-temporal multipliers used in calculating the

effects of counterfactual shocks in some unit(s) on its/their own outcomes and those of other units

over time, i.e., spatio-temporal response-paths, or the long-run steady-state (LRSS) effects of such

shocks, accounting both temporal and spatial dynamics. We also apply the delta method to derive

analytically the asymptotic approximate standard errors for these response-path and LRSS estimates.

Calculating the cumulative LRSS spatio-temporal effects is most convenient working with the

Page 23: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 21 of 28

spatio-temporal-lag model in (Nx1) vector form:

1t N t t t tρ ϕ −= + + +y W y y X β ε (10).

To find the long-run, steady-state, equilibrium (cumulative) level of y, we set yt-1 equal to y in (10)

and solve. This gives the steady-state effect, assuming stationarity41 and that the exogenous right-

hand-side (RHS) terms, X and ε, fix permanently to their hypothetical/counterfactual levels:42

( ) [ ] ( )

( ) ( )

1N N

11,2 1,N

2,1

1

(N 1),N

N,1 N,(N 1)

11

11

t N t t t t N t t t N t t

t t t t

w ww

ww w

ρ ϕ ρ ϕ ρ ϕ

ϕ ρ ρρ ϕ

ϕ ρρ ρ ϕ

= + + + = + + + = − − +

− − −⎡ ⎤⎢ ⎥− −⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥= + ≡ +⎢ ⎥− −⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥− − −⎣ ⎦

y W y y X β ε W I y X β ε I W I X β ε

X β ε S X β ε(11).

To offer standard-error estimates for these LRSS estimates, we use the delta method. That gives a

first-order Taylor-series linear-approximation to nonlinear (11) around the estimated parameter-

values and determines the asymptotic variance of that linear approximation. Here, denote the ith

column of S as si and its estimate as ˆis . The LRSS spatio-temporal effects of a permanent one-unit

increase in εt in unit i, for example, are then ˆis , and the delta-method standard-errors of ˆis are:

( ) ( ) [ ]

th

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆˆ ˆˆ ˆ ˆ, where , , andˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ and are the i columns of and , respectivelyˆ ˆ

i i i i ii

i i

ρ ϕρ ϕ

ρ ϕ

′ ⎡ ⎤∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤′= ≡ ≡ ⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ∂ ∂∂ ∂ ∂⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤∂ ∂⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥∂ ∂⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦

s s s s sV s V θ θθ θ θ

s s SWS SS

(12).

Analogously, the LRSS spatio-temporal effects of a permanent one-unit increase in explanatory

variable k in country i are ˆˆi kβs , with delta-method standard-errors of:

( ) ( )th

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆˆ ˆ ˆ ˆˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ, where , ,ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ

ˆ ˆˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆand and are the i columns of and ˆ ˆ

i k i k i k i k i ki k k i

i k i kk k

β β β β ββ ρ ϕ βρ ϕ

β β β βρ ϕ

′⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤∂ ∂ ∂ ∂ ∂′⎡ ⎤= ≡ ≡⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦ ∂ ∂∂ ∂ ∂⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤∂ ∂⎢ ⎥ ⎢ ⎥∂ ∂⎣ ⎦ ⎣ ⎦

s s s s sV s V θ θ sθ θ θ

s s SWS S , respectivelyS

(13).

The spatio-temporal response-path of the Nx1 vector of unit outcomes, yt, to some counterfactual

Page 24: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 22 of 28

path of the exogenous RHS terms, X and ε, can be traced by rearranging (10) to isolate yt on the left:

[ ] { } { }11 2 1t N N t t t t t tρ ϕ ϕ−

− −= − + + ≡ + +y I W y X β ε S y X β ε (14).

This formula gives the response-paths of all units {i} to hypothetical shocks to X or ε in any unit(s)

{j}, including a shock in {i} itself/themselves, by inserting those counterfactual shocks in Xtβ+ε in

the row(s) corresponding to {j}. To calculate marginal spatio-temporal effects (non-cumulative) or

plot the over-time path of the effect of a permanent one-unit change in an explanatory variable

(cumulative), and their standard errors, working with the entire NTxNT matrix is easier. Redefine S1

in (11) as [ ] 13 NT NT NTρ ϕ −≡ − −S I W M and proceed as before. Web appendix material includes the

spreadsheet, perhaps useful as a template, in which we calculate such spatio-temporally dynamic and

LRSS effects in the substantive interpretation and presentation of our empirical reanalysis below.

VI. Internal vs. External Determinants of Fiscal Policy: A Reanalysis of Swank & Steinmo

We explained above (and showed elsewhere) how empirical specifications that omit spatial lags

assume zero interdependence by construction and that this induces omitted-variable bias that inflates

estimates of the effects of non-spatial model-components. In the present substantive context, this

means most extant studies of globalization, having neglected spatial lags, have likely overestimated

the role of domestic and exogenous-external conditions while preventing any globalization-induced

interdependence from manifesting empirically. Conversely, we also explained how (and previously

showed that) OLS regression estimates of models including spatial lags, which have become more

common lately among scholars of globalization and diffusion, greatly improve upon previous non-

spatial models but also suffer simultaneity biases that will tend to inflate interdependence-strength

estimates at the expense of domestic and exogenous-external explanators. Estimation by S-ML of the

spatio-temporal-lag model as described above effectively redresses both issues. Lastly, we showed

how to calculate and present the spatio-temporally dynamic effects estimated in such an approach, so

next we provide example of all this in reanalyzing the capital-tax regressions from Swank & Steinmo

Page 25: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 23 of 28

(2002), taking potential strategic policy-interdependence across countries into account.

Swank & Steinmo (2002) stress domestic factors—especially budgetary dynamics, public-sector

debt, and macroeconomic performance—in their noteworthy study of tax-policy reform in OECD

countries. They also find some external factors important, namely a country’s capital-account and

trade openness. However, all their models omit spatial lags, thereby assuming country’s responses to

changing internal or external political-economic conditions to be independent. Perhaps as a result,

some findings seem unintuitive. Capital mobility and trade exposure reduce marginal statutory, but

not effective, capital-tax-rates, and capital mobility reduces effective labor, but not capital, tax-rates.

Swank & Steinmo suggest policymakers may combine statutory-rate cuts with eliminating some

investment incentives, leaving effective tax-burdens static, but why this should achieve any political

or economic effect is unclear. They suggest mobile capital may yield lower effective labor-tax-rates

because labor taxes raise nonwage costs, eroding profits, but this would apply at least as strongly to

capital taxes. Finally, they report panel-corrected standard-errors (PCSE), as has become standard

practice for TSCS data in CP/CPE. PCSE implicitly recognizes spatial correlation, if not necessarily

interdependence, in “correcting” standard errors, but it is treated as nuisance to correct rather than as

potentially further evidence of external effects on tax policy. Swank and Steinmo conclude that their

results “are consistent with the argument that, while internationalization has influenced the shift in

tax-policy content, the combined effect of statutory tax-rate cuts and base-broadening reductions in

investment incentives has left the effective tax burden on capital largely unchanged.” In relegating

spatial correlation to adjusting standard errors, the spatial-nuisance approach abets such conclusions

because any actual interdependence in the data is, in a cliché, “out of sight, out of mind.”

Swank (2006) greatly advanced this agenda, focusing squarely on spatial interdependence in tax

policy. He estimates several spatio-temporal-lag models with spatial-weights, wij, specified to reflect

three possible pathways: competition for foreign direct investment (FDI), policy learning, and social

emulation. The first W weighs equally (i.e., it averages) all j≠i countries in the sample. The second

Page 26: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 24 of 28

weighs j by the strength of i’s and j’s competition for capital, measuring that by total dyadic trade-

and FDI-flows and the correlation of their direct-investment portfolios. The third gives positive wij

for countries in the same family of nations (as defined therein) and wij=0 otherwise. However, he

finds support only for a fourth spatial-lag structure in which U.S. capital-tax-policy alone influences

other countries’ capital-tax reforms—the U.S. as unmoved mover—with this effect being conditional

on a country’s domestic politics, production regime, and economic integration with the U.S.

These are significant advances, but others occur to us as well. First, Swank ignores geographic

proximity, which plays an important role in inter-jurisdictional competition, including for FDI, via

human and capital migration directly but also, often more strongly, through third-party effects. As

we noted in a labor-market-policy context (2006b), economic-interdependence effects incur strongly

at borders. This derives, in part, from the tendency of firms to cluster operations around and across

borders to minimize transport and related costs while capitalizing maximally on legal-institutional,

especially tax-system, discontinuities at borders. Also, recent research in economics (e.g., Blonigen

et al. 2004, Abreu & Melendez 2006, Guerin 2006) finds that multinational enterprises (MNE’s) use

host countries as export platforms to nearby markets, again suggesting a major role for contiguity

and geographic proximity in shaping which countries compete for FDI. Much of FDI to Ireland, for

instance, goes to produce goods for export to continental Europe. Ireland and Britain thus compete

not only for each other’s capital but also for FDI from third countries as, e.g., U.S. MNE’s may see

Ireland and Britain as substitutable bases for export to continental, especially Benelux and French,

markets. Portugal and Spain likely compete similarly; Canada competes with the U.S. for FDI from

third countries in a way that Germany, e.g., does not; etc. Policy in one jurisdiction thus attracts or

repels FDI in bordering jurisdictions, and so bordering countries’ policymaking will be especially

interdependent. Additionally, spatial-weights based on borders have stronger claim to exogeneity

than would weights based on FDI or trade flows, e.g., on which taxation likely has sizable effect.43

Second, Swank uses the strategy of time-lagged spatial-lags described above. As we discussed, if

Page 27: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 25 of 28

interdependence incurs within an observational period, which, as also discussed, seems very likely in

capital-tax competition, this strategy incurs (likely positive) simultaneity bias. It also misses within-

period action, which would instead favor underestimating interdependence-strength. We apply the S-

ML estimator sketched above, using a contemporaneous binary-contiguity spatial-lag described

below, and find strong evidence of within-period spatial interdependence in capital-tax policy based

on contiguity. We then show how to interpret and present such spatio-temporal-effect estimates.

[Table 1 Here]

We focus on the capital- and labor-tax-rate results in Swank & Steinmo’s Table 2 (pp. 653-4).

Their sample covers 195 observations from 13 countries, 1981-95. We add a spatial lag to their first-

order temporal-lag model, yielding a specification like generic model (8) above. We calculated our

spatial lag, Wy, using a standardized binary contiguity-weights matrix which begins by coding wij=1

for countries i and j that share a border and wij=0 for countries that do not border (except we code

France, Belgium, and the Netherlands as bordering Britain). Table 1 lists the countries and their

neighbors. We then row-standardize (as is standard in spatial-econometrics) the resulting matrix by

dividing each element by its row’s sum, making Wy the simple average of y in i’s neighbors.

[Table 2 Here]

Table 2 presents the original results and our reanalyses including the spatial lag. We report two

sets of estimates for each tax rate, one for a model with both unit (country) and period (year) fixed-

effects and one for a model with unit fixed-effects only.44 In sum, we find very differently regarding

the importance of external factors, especially interdependence, for capital taxes. Among external

factors, the non-spatial model found statistically significant effects only of capital-account openness,

only on labor taxes. In the reanalyses, contrarily, spatial-lag-coefficient estimates suggest positive

interdependence in all models, and substantively and statistically significantly so in capital taxes.

Effective capital-tax-rates in one country statistically significantly impinge upon effective capital-

tax-rates in others. Moreover, some coefficients on domestic variables that the non-spatial model

Page 28: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 26 of 28

found substantively and statistically significant are smaller and insignificant in the spatio-temporal

model, notably the elderly population and Christian-Democratic government (domestic conditions

that therefore must cluster spatially). Thus, as we expected, non-spatial analysis of international tax-

competition understated interdependence strength and overestimated some domestic factors’ roles.

The labor-tax-rate estimates provide stark contrast. In neither case does the spatial-lag coefficient

achieve statistical significance. Not surprisingly then, our spatial-lag-model estimates, particularly

for the one including unit and period fixed-effects, are almost identical to Swank and Steinmo’s non-

spatial-model estimates. Strategic policy-interdependence in labor taxation is weaker or absent. This

result is intuitive and consistent with Franzese & Mosher’s (2002) arguments regarding the centrality

of liquid-capital mobility in producing tax-competition. Workers are far less mobile than capital, so

we would expect to find far less evidence of strategic policy interdependence in labor taxes.

[Table 3 Here]

Table 3 gives estimates of the spatial effects of counterfactual shocks to structural unemployment

in eleven sample countries. The cells report estimated effects of unit increases in column-country

structural-unemployment on row-country capital-tax-rates. The first number is the estimated first-

period effect (direct effect plus spatial feedback), calculated using (14). For example, the immediate

spatial effect (i.e., post-spatial but pre-temporal dynamics) of a unit increase in German structural

employment on all thirteen countries is s6β5, where s6 is the sixth column of S (Germany’s column in

the spatial-multiplier) as defined in (14) and β5 is the fifth row of the column-vector β (structural

unemployment is x5). The second number is the standard error of this estimate, from (13) with i=6,

k=5; and the last number is the estimated LRSS effect of a permanent unit-increase, from (11). For

instance, we estimate a unit permanent increase in German structural unemployment produces a

LRSS 7%-reduction in Germany’s capital-tax rate, which, along the way, induces France to lower its

LRSS capital-tax rate by almost 1.4%. We can also effectively express a column of these estimates,

say the fifth, again giving the first-period and the LRSS responses to a one-unit increase in German

Page 29: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 27 of 28

structural-unemployment across all the countries, chorographically in a pair of maps as in Figure 2.

[Figure 2 Here]

Figure 3 and Figure 4 present temporal response paths to this counterfactual shock to German

structural unemployment. We calculate each using the ith column of S1≡[INT-ρWNT-φMNT]-1 times βk.

Figure 3 gives the over-time marginal-response (year-on-year) in Germany’s own capital-tax-rate,

including all spatial-feedback, with standard-error bands reflecting a 90% confidence interval. The

cumulative effect after 15 periods is -6.523, just over 90% of the LRSS effect. Figure 4 plots the

marginal first-order spatial-effects from a one-unit increase in German structural-unemployment on

French capital-tax rates.45 An increase in German structural unemployment leads to a decrease in

German capital-tax-rates, and this, in turn, produces a decrease in French capital-tax-rates. Roughly

68% of the steady state effect (-.943/-1.395) is felt in the first 15 periods after the shock.

[Figure 3 and Figure 4 Here]

VII. Conclusion

Does international economic integration (i.e., globalization) constrain national governments in

their attempt to redistribute income, risk, and opportunity through tax-and-expenditure policy? In

this paper, we have shown that, in overlooking the degree and manner to/in which fiscal policies

correlate spatially (i.e., across countries), previous attempts to answer this and related questions

empirically have missed important evidence of globalization’s appreciable influence on domestic

policymaking. We have shown formally and generally how positive and negative cross-jurisdictional

externalities of policies induce, respectively, negative and positive strategic interdependence of

domestic policies. Globalization and the implied heightened competition for capital therefore clearly

imply capital-tax policies in one country will be influenced by those of its “neighbors.” Previous

regression models that ignored the policy interdependence that globalization implies were therefore

seriously misspecified and likely subject to omitted-variable bias that inflated their estimates of

domestic and exogenous-external factors’ impacts while effectively preventing any empirical

Page 30: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Text: Page 28 of 28

manifestation of globalization effects via interdependence. We showed how to model such strategic

policy-interdependence with spatial lags, discussed some crucial issues in the specification and

estimation of such models and drawing valid empirical inferences from their estimates, and offered

some suggestions on effective presentation of the spatio-temporally dynamic effect-estimates yielded

by these models. We then reanalyzed Swank and Steinmo’s (2002) influential study of OECD tax-

reform to illustrate the specification, estimation, and presentation of the spatial-lag models that can

reflect more accurately the substance and theory of globalization and interdependence. In that re-

analysis, we discovered that capital-tax-rate policies are substantively and statistically significantly

interdependent, and thus that previous estimates do indeed seem to have been misleading in the ways

our analysis would suggest. Labor being far less mobile across jurisdictions, we also found,

intuitively, far less sign of significant strategic policy-interdependence in labor tax-rates and thus no

such appreciable biases in previously reported results on that policy dimension.

Page 31: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 1 of 8

REFERENCES

Abreau, M., Melendez, J. 2006. “Spatial Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment.” Presented at

the 4th Annual Conference of the Euro-Latin Study Network on Integration and Trade (ELSNIT):

An Initiative of the Inter-American Development Bank Paris, France, October 20-21.

Alesina, A., Roubini, N., Cohen, G.D. 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. MIT Press.

Alesina, A, Summers, L. 1993. “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance:

Some Comparative Evidence,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25(2):151-63.

Alvarez, R.M., Garrett, G. Lange, P. 1991. “Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and

Macroeconomic Performance,” American Political Science Review 85:539-56.

Anselin, L. 1988. Spatial Econometrics: Methods and Models. Boston: Kluwer Academic.

Anselin, L. 2006. Spatial Econometrics. In T.C. Mills and K. Patterson, eds., Palgrave Handbook of

Econometrics: Volume 1, Econometric Theory. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 901-941.

Basinger, S., Hallerberg, M. 2004. “Remodeling the Competition for Capital: How Domestic Politics

Erases the Race-to-the-Bottom,” American Political Science Review 98(2):261-76.

Beck, N., Gleditsch, K. S., Beardsley, K. 2006. “Space is more than geography: Using spatial

econometrics in the study of political economy.” International Studies Quarterly 50:27–44.

Beck, N., Katz, J. 1995. “What To Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series-Cross-Section Data in

Comparative Politics,” American Political Science Review 89(3):634-47.

Beck, N., Katz, J. 1996. “Nuisance vs. Substance: Specifying and Estimating Time-Series-Cross-

Section Models,” Political Analysis 6:1-36.

Beissinger, M. 2007. “Structure and Example in Modular Political Phenomena: The Diffusion of

Bulldozer/Rose/Orange/Tulip Revolutions,” Perspectives on Politics 5: 259-276.

Berry, F. 1994. “Sizing up State Policy Innovation Research,” Policy Studies Journal 22(3):442-56.

Besley, T., Coate, S. 1997. “An Economic Model of Representative Democracy,” Quarterly Journal

of Economics 112(1):85-.

Blonigen, B., Tomlin, K., Wilson, W.W. 2004. “Tariff-jumping FDI and Domestic Firms’ Profits.”

Canadian Journal of Economics 37(3):656-77.

Boehmke, F., Witmer, R. 2004. “Disentangling Diffusion: The Effects of Social Learning and

Page 32: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 2 of 8

Economic Competition on State Policy Innovation and Expansion,” Political Research Quarterly

57(1):39–51.

Boix, C. 1998. Political Parties, Growth and Equality. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Braun, D., Gilardi, F. 2006. “Taking ‘Galton’s Problem’ Seriously: Towards a Theory of Policy

Diffusion,” Journal of Theoretical Politics 18(3):298–322.

Brinks, D., Coppedge, M. 2006. “Diffusion Is No Illusion: Neighbor Emulation in the Third Wave

of Democracy,” Comparative Political Studies 39(4):463-89.

Brueckner, J. K. 2003. “Strategic interaction among governments: An overview of empirical

studies.” International Regional Science Review, 26(2):175–188.

Brune, N., Guisinger, A. 2007. “Myth or Reality? The Diffusion of Financial Liberalization in

Developing Countries,” Yale University MacMillan Center Working Paper.

Bunce, V., Wolchik, S. 2006. “Favorable Conditions and International Support: The Wave of

Electoral Revolutions in Post-Communist Countries,” Journal of Democracy 17(4):5-18.

Bunce, V., Wolchik, S. 2007. “Transnational Networks, Diffusion Dynamics, and Electoral

Revolutions in the Postcommunist World,” Physica A 378(1):92-9.

Caldeira, G. 1985. “The Transmission of Legal Precedent: A Study of State Supreme Courts,”

American Political Science Review 79(1):178–94.

Cameron, D. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy,” American Political Science Review

72:1243.

Cameron, D. 1984. “Social Democracy, Corporatism, Labor Quiescence, and the Representation of

Economic Interest in Advanced Capitalist Society,” in Goldthorpe, J.H., ed., Order and Conflict

in Contemporary Capitalism. New York: Oxford UP, pp. 143-78.

Cho, W.T., Gimpel, J. 2007. “Prospecting for (Campaign) Gold,” American Journal of Political

Science 51(2): 255-68.

Cho, W.T., Rudolph, T. 2007. “Emanating Political Participation: Untangling the Spatial Structure

behind Participation,” British Journal of Political Science 37(2):313-32.

Crain, R. 1966. “Fluoridation: Diffusion of an Innovation among Cities,” Social Forces 44:467-76.

Cukierman, A. 1992. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Page 33: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 3 of 8

Dahl, R. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press.

Eising, R. 2002. “Policy Learning in Embedded Negotiations: Explaining EU Electricity

Liberalization,” International Organization 56(1):85–120.

Elhorst, J.P. 2001. “Dynamic models in space and time.” Geographical Analysis 33:119–140.

Elkins, Z., Simmons, B. 2005. “On Waves, Clusters, and Diffusion: A Conceptual Framework,”

Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 598(1):33–51.

Franzese, R. 2002. Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Franzese, R. 2003. “BOOK REVIEW: Duane Swank, Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy

Change,” Political Science Quarterly 118(1):172-3.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2003. “Modeling Spatial Relationships in International and Comparative

Political Economy: An Application to Globalization and Capital Taxation in Developed

Democracies,” presented at the Annual Meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2004. “Empirical Modeling Strategies for Spatial Interdependence: Omitted-

Variable vs. Simultaneity Biases,” presented at the 21st Summer Meeting of the Society for

Political Methodology (http://polmeth.wustl.edu/retrieve.php?id=38).

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2006a. “Spatio-Temporal Models for Political-Science Panel and Time-Series-

Cross-Section Data,” presented at the 23rd Meeting of the Society for Political Methodology

(www.umich.edu/~franzese/FranzeseHays.S.ST.EconometricsForPS.PolMeth06.pdf).

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2006b. “Strategic Interaction among EU Governments in Active-Labor-

Market Policymaking: Subsidiarity and Policy Coordination under the European Employment

Strategy,” European Union Politics 7(2):167-89.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2007a. “Empirical Models of International Capital-Tax Competition,” in G.

Gregoriou, C. Read, eds., International Taxation Handbook, Elsevier Press: 43-72.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2007b. “Interdependence in Comparative & International Political Economy,

with Applications to Economic Integration and Strategic Fiscal-Policy Interdependence,”

presented at Paris 13 (Université Paris), Axe 5: PSE.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2007c. “Spatial-Econometric Models of Cross-Sectional Interdependence in

Political-Science Panel and Time-Series-Cross-Section Data,” Political Analysis 15(2):140-64.

Page 34: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 4 of 8

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2007d. “The Spatial Probit Model of Interdependent Binary Outcomes:

Estimation, Interpretation, and Presentation,” presented at the 24th Summer Meeting of the

Society for Political Methodology (http://polmeth.wustl.edu/retrieve.php?id=715).

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2008a. “Empirical Modeling of Spatial Interdependence in Time-Series Cross-

Sections,” in S. Pickel, G. Pickel, H-J. Lauth, D. Jahn, eds., Neuere Entwicklungen und

Anwendungen auf dem Gebiet der Methoden der vergleichenden Politikwissenschaft, Band II.

Wiesbaden: Westdeutscher Verlag, forthcoming.

Franzese, R., Hays, J. 2008b. “Empirical Models of Spatial Interdependence,” J. Box-Steffensmeier,

H. Brady, D. Collier, eds., Oxford Handbook of Political Methodology, Oxford UP.

Franzese, R., Mosher, J. 2002. “Comparative Institutional Advantage: The Scope for Divergence

within European Economic Integration.” European Union Politics 3(2):177-204.

Garrett, G. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Garrett, G., Mitchell, D. 2001. “Globalization, Government Spending and Taxation in the OECD,”

European Journal of Political Research 39(2):145-77.

Genschel, P. 2002. “Globalization, Tax Competition, and the Welfare State,” Politics and Society

30(2):245–75.

Gleditsch, K.S. 2002. All International Politics is Local: The Diffusion of Conflict, Integration, and

Democratization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

Gleditsch, K.S. 2007. “Civil War and its Spread,” in J. Bercovitch, V. Kremenyuk, I.W. Zartman,

eds., Handbook on Conflict Resolution. London: Sage. Forthcoming.

Gleditsch, K.S., Ward, M. 2006. “Diffusion and the International Context of Democratization,”

International Organization 60(4): 911–33.

Gleditsch, K.S., Ward, M. 2007. “Diffusion and the Spread of Democratic Institutions,” in F.

Dobbins, G. Garret, B. Simmons, eds. The Global Diffusion of Democracy and Markets.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Goldenberg, E.N., Traugott, M.W., Baumgartner, F.K. 1986. “Preemptive and Reactive Spending in

U.S. House Races.” Political Behavior 8:3-20.

Govea, R., West, G. 1981. “Riot Contagion in Latin America, 1949-1963,” Journal of Conflict

Page 35: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 5 of 8

Resolution 25(2):349-368.

Gray, V. 1973. “Innovation in the States: A Diffusion Study,” American Political Science Review

67(4):1174–85.

Guerin, S.S. 2006. “The Role of Geography in Financial and Economic Integration: A Comparative

Analysis of Foreign Direct Investment, Trade and Portfolio Investment Flows.” The World

Economy 29(2):189-209.

Hagopian, F., Mainwaring, S., eds. 2005. The Third Wave of Democratization in Latin America:

Advances and Setbacks. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Hall, P., Soskice, D., eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford UP.

Hays, J. 2003. “Globalization and Capital Taxation in Consensus and Majoritarian Democracies,”

World Politics 56(3):79–113.

Hibbs, D. 1987. The American Political Economy. Cambridge: Harvard UP.

Hines, J. 1999. “Lessons from Behavioral Responses to International Taxation,” National Tax

Journal 52(2):305–22.

Huckfeldt, R., Sprague, J. 1991. “Discussant Effects on Vote Choice: Intimacy, Structure, and

Interdependence.” The Journal of Politics 53 (1): 122-158.

Huckfeldt, R., Sprague, J. 1993. “Citizens, Contexts, and Politics,” in A.W. Finifter, ed., Political

Science: The State of the Discipline II. Washington, DC: APSA, pp. 281-303.

Huckfeldt, R., Johnson, P.E., Sprague, J. 2005. " Individuals, Dyads and Networks: Autoregressive

Patterns of Political Influence," in Alan S. Zuckerman (ed.), The Social Logic of Politics:

Personal Networks as Contexts for Political Behavior. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

Huntington, S. 1991. The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: The

University of Oklahoma Press.

Iversen, T., Cusack, T. 2000. “Causes of Welfare State Expansion,” World Politics 52(2):313–49.

Kayser, M.A. 2007. “Partisan Waves: International Sources of Electoral Choice,” unpublished.

University of Rochester. http://mail.rochester.edu/~mksr/papers/PWaves_ECM_070108.pdf.

Kelejian, H.H., Murrell, P., Shepotylo, O. 2007. “Spatial interdependence and relative geographical

location as determinants of institutional development.” Working paper:

Page 36: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 6 of 8

http://kei.org.ua/files/Governance%20and%20geography%20August%2022.pdf.

Lacombe, D.J., Shaughnessy, T.M. 2005. “An Examination of a Congressional Vote Using Bayesian

Spatial Probit Techniques,” presented at the Annual Meetings of the Public Choice Society.

Lacombe, D.J., Shaughnessy, T.M. 2007. “Accounting for Spatial Error Correlation in the 2004

Presidential Popular Vote” Public Finance Review 35 (4): 480-499.

Lange, P, Garrett, G. 1985. “The Politics of Growth.” Journal of Politics 47:792-827.

Lee, C-K., Strang, D. 2006. “The International Diffusion of Public-Sector Downsizing: Network

Emulation and Theory-Driven Learning.” International Organization, 60(4): 883-909.

Li, R., Thompson, W. 1975. “The ‘Coup Contagion’ Hypothesis,” Journal of Conflict Resolution

19(1):63–88.

Lin, T-M., Wu, C- E., Lee, F-Y. 2006. “‘Neighborhood’ influence on the formation of national

identity in Taiwan,” Political Research Quarterly 59:35–46.

McAdam, D., Rucht, D. 1993. “The Cross-National Diffusion of Movement Ideas,” Annals of the

American Academy of Political and Social Science 528:56-74.

Meseguer, C. 2004. “What Role for Learning? The Diffusion of Privatisation in OECD and Latin

American Countries,” Journal of Public Policy 24(3):299–325.

Murdoch, J.C., Sandler, T. 2004. “Civil Wars and Economic Growth: Spatial Dispersion,” American

Journal of Political Science 48(1):138-51.

Oates, W. 2001. “Fiscal Competition and European Union: Contrasting Perspectives,” Regional

Science and Urban Economics 31(2–3):133–45.

O'Loughlin, J., Flint, C., Anselin, L. 1994. “The Geography of the Nazi Vote: Context, Confession,

and Class in the Reichstag Election of 1930.” Annals of the Association of American

Geographers 84 (3): 351-380.

O’Loughlin, J., Ward, M., Lofdahl, C., Cohen, J., Brown, D., Reilly, D., Gleditsch, K., Shin, M.

1998. “The Diffusion of Democracy, 1946–1994,” Annals of the Association of American

Geographers 88(4):545–74.

Ord, J. K. 1975. “Estimation methods for models of spatial interaction.” Journal of the American

Statistical Association, 70:120–126.

Page 37: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 7 of 8

Page, S.E. 2006. “Path Dependence,” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 87–115.

Persson, T., Tabellini, G. 2000. Political Economics. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Pierson, P. 1994. Dismantling the Welfare State? Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Plümper, T., Schneider, C. 2006. “The Computation of Convergence, or: How to Chase a Black Cat

in a Dark Room,” unpublished: University of Essex.

Powell, G.B., Whitten, G.D. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking

Account of the Political Context,” American Journal of Political Science 37(2):391-414.

Quinn, D. 1997. “The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation,” American

Political Science Review 91(3):531-52.

Redoano, M. 2003. “Fiscal Interactions among European Countries,” Warwick Economic Research

Papers No. 680.

Ripley, B. D. 1981. Spatial Statistics. Wiley, New York.

Rodrik, D. 1997. Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington: Institute for International

Economics.

Rydgren, J. 2005. “Is Extreme Right-Wing Populism Contagious? Explaining the Emergence of a

New Party Family,” European Journal of Political Research 44(3):413–437.

Scheve, K., Slaughter, M. 2004. “Economic Insecurity and the Globalization of Production,”

American Journal of Political Science 48(4):662-74.

Schneider, A., Ingram, H. 1988. “Systematically ‘Pinching’ Ideas: A Comparative Approach to

Policy Design,” Journal of Public Policy 8(1):61–80.

Shin, M.E., Agnew, J. 2002. “The Geography of Party Replacement in Italy.” Political Geography

21 (2): 221-242.

Shipan, C., Volden, C. 2006. “Bottom-Up Federalism: The Diffusion of Antismoking Policies from

U.S. Cities to States,” American Journal of Political Science 50(4), 825–843.

Simmons, B., Elkins, Z. 2004. The “Globalization of Liberalization: Policy Diffusion in the

International Political Economy.” American Political Science Review 98 (1):171-89.

Simmons, B., Dobbin, F., Garrett, G. 2006. “Introduction: The International Diffusion of

Liberalism,” International Organization 60(4):781–810.

Page 38: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 8 of 8

Starr, H. 1991. “Democratic Dominoes: Diffusion Approaches to the Spread of Democracy in the

International System,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35(2):356–81.

Swank, D. 1998. “Funding the Welfare State: Globalization and the Taxation of Business in

Advanced Market Economies,” Political Studies 46(4):671–92.

Swank, D. 2002. Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare

States. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Swank, D. 2006. “Tax Policy in an Era of Internationalization: Explaining the Spread of

Neoliberalism,” International Organization 60: 847-82.

Swank, D., Steinmo, S. 2002. “The New Political Economy of Taxation in Advanced Capitalist

Democracies,” American Journal of Political Science 46(3):477–89.

Swaroop, S., Morenoff, J. D. 2006. “Building Community: The Neighborhood Context of Social

Organization,” Social Forces 84(3):1665-96.

Tufte, E. 1978. Political Control of the Economy. Princeton: Princeton UP.

Walker, J. 1969. “The Diffusion of Innovations among the American States.” American Political

Science Review 63(3):880–99.

Wildasin, D. 1989. “Interjurisdictional Capital Mobility: Fiscal Externality and a Corrective

Subsidy,” Journal of Urban Economics 25(2):193–212.

Wilson, J. 1986. “A Theory of Interregional Tax Competition,” Journal of Urban Economics

19(3):296–315.

Wilson, J. 1999. “Theories of Tax Competition,” National Tax Journal 52(2):269–304.

Zodrow, G., Mieszkowski, P. 1986. “The New View of the Property Tax: A Reformulation,”

Regional Science and Urban Economics 16(3):309–327.

Page 39: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Authors’ Bios, Acknowledgements

Authors’ Bios and Acknowledgements

Robert J. Franzese, Jr. is Associate Professor of Political Science at the University of Michigan, Ann Arbor and author or co-author of Macroeconomic Policies of Developed Democracies (Cambridge University Press, 2002), Modeling and Interpreting Interactive Hypotheses in Regression Analysis (University of Michigan Press, 2007), and, with Hays, Spatial-Econometric Models of Interdependence (in progress), co-editor of Institutional Conflicts and Complementarities (Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2004), and has authored or co-authored articles appearing in American Journal of Political Science, International Organization, Political Analysis, Annual Review of Political Science, European Union Politics, Climactic Change, and Empirica, and numerous chapters in edited volumes including one in each of the Oxford Handbooks of…Political Economy, …Comparative Politics, and …Political Methodology. His work has been translated into at least three languages (German, Japanese, and Chinese) and has won the Sage Award for best article in European Union Politics in 2006, the Warren E. Miller Award for best article in Political Analysis in 2005, the Gregory Luebbert Award for best article in field of comparative politics published in 1997/98 and the Pi Sigma Alpha Award for best paper presented at 1998 Midwest Political Science Association Annual Meetings. Jude C. Hays is Assistant Professor of Political Science at the University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign and author or co-author of Globalization, Domestic Institutions, and the New Politics of Embedded Liberalism (Oxford University Press, forthcoming), and, with Franzese, Spatial-Econometric Models of Interdependence (in progress). He has authored or co-authored articles appearing in American Journal of Political Science, International Organization, World Politics, Political Analysis, International Studies Quarterly, European Union Politics, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, and Alternatives, and several chapters in edited volumes including the Oxford Handbook of Political Methodology, the International Taxation Handbook, and Computational Models in Political Economy. He has won the Sage Award for best article in European Union Politics in 2006 and three awards for excellence in undergraduate and graduate teaching at the University of Illinois. Acknowledgements: * This research was supported in part by NSF grant #0318045. We thank Chris Achen, Jim Alt, Kenichi Ariga, Klaus Armingeon, Neal Beck, Jake Bowers, Jim Caporaso, Kerwin Charles, Bryce Corrigan, Tom Cusack, David Darmofal, Jakob de Haan, Scott De Marchi, John Dinardo, Zach Elkins, John Freeman, Fabrizio Gilardi, Kristian Gleditsch, Mark Hallerberg, John Jackson, Aya Kachi, Jonathan Katz, Mark Kayser, Achim Kemmerling, Gary King, Hasan Kirmanoglu, Herbert Kitschelt, Jim Kuklinski, Tse-Min Lin, Xiaobo Lu, Walter Mebane, Covadonga Meseguer, Michael Peress, Thomas Pluemper, Dennis Quinn, Megan Reif, Frances Rosenbluth, Ken Scheve, Phil Schrodt, Chuck Shipan, Beth Simmons, David Siroky, John D. Stephens, Duane Swank, Wendy Tam-Cho, Vera Troeger, Craig Volden, Michael Ward, Greg Wawro, and Erik Wibbels for useful comments on this and/or other work in our broader project on spatial-econometric models in political science. We alone are responsible for any errors.

Page 40: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 1 of 7

Table 1: Sample Countries and their “Neighbors” “Neighbors”

Australia None Belgium France, Germany, Netherlands, UK Canada US Finland Norway, Sweden France Belgium, Germany, Italy, UK

Germany Belgium, France, Netherlands Italy France

Japan None Netherlands Belgium, Germany, UK

Norway Finland, Sweden Sweden Finland, Norway

United Kingdom Belgium, France, Netherlands United States Canada

Page 41: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 2 of 7

Table 2: Reanalysis of Swank & Steinmo (2002, Appendix Table 2) Effective Tax Rate on Capital Effective Tax Rate on Labor

Swank & Steinmo

Reanalysis (1)

Reanalysis (2)

Swank & Steinmo

Reanalysis (3)

Reanalysis (4)

Temporal Lag 0.809** 0.808** (0.05)

0.864** (0.048) 0.671** 0.66**

(0.054) 0.711** (0.054)

Spatial Lag 0.104* (0.054)

0.126** (0.054) 0.017

(0.058) 0.05

(0.055)

Liberalization 1.146 1.235* (0.725)

0.629 (0.702) -.261** -0.255**

(0.102) -0.168* (0.091)

Trade -0.018 0.009 (0.064)

0.005 (0.061) -0.009 0.001

(0.023) -0.001 (0.023)

Structural Unemployment -1.147** -1.218**

(0.306) -1.033** (0.283) -0.359** -0.38**

(0.189) -0.148 (0.189)

Public Sector Debt 0.089** 0.099** (0.036)

0.046 (0.032) 0.053** 0.056**

(0.014) 0.038** (0.013)

Elderly Population 1.264** 1.011 (0.615)

-0.08 (0.481) -0.018 0.03

(0.23) 0.171

(0.184)

Growth 0.230* 0.242 (0.151)

0.307** (0.147) -0.008 -0.009

(0.051) 0.009

(0.051)

% Change in Profits 0.127** 0.136** (0.055)

0.174** (0.054)

Domestic Investment 0.066 0.045 (0.055)

0.059 (0.049)

Inflation 0.115** 0.115** (0.05)

0.063 (0.043)

Unemployment 0.280** 0.296** (0.084)

0.144* (0.079)

Left Government 0.018** 0.018* (0.01)

0.012 (0.01) 0.008** 0.008**

(0.004) 0.007* (0.004)

Christian Democratic Government 0.041** 0.035

(0.028) 0.01

(0.026) 0.001 0.002 (0.011)

0.009 (0.01)

Fixed Effects: Ctry, Yr Ctry, Yr1 Ctry Ctry, Yr Ctry, Yr1 Ctry R2 .928 .922 .914 .989 .989 .988

NOTES: Parentheses contain standard errors. **, * = significant at 5%, 10% level, respectively. 1=Biannual period effects.

Page 42: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 3 of 7

Table 3: Short-Run and Steady-State Spatial Effects from a Shock to Structural Unemployment BEL CAN FIN FRA GER ITA NTH NOR SWE GBR USA

BEL -1.22** 0.307 -7.403

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.034* 0.021 -1.672

-0.034* 0.02 -1.51

-0.001 0.001 -0.227

-0.034* 0.021 -1.549

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.034* 0.02 -1.51

0 0 0

CAN

0 0 0

-1.23** 0.309 -8.994

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.128* 0.074 -4.876

FIN

0 0 0

0 0 0

-1.23** 0.307 -7.954

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

0 0 0

0 0 0

FRA

-0.034* 0.021 -1.672

0 0 0

0 0 0

-1.224** 0.307 -7.643

-0.033* 0.019 -1.395

-0.032* 0.018 -1.036

-0.003 0.003 -0.731

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.033* 0.019 -1.395

0 0 0

GER

-0.045* 0.027 -2.013

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.044* 0.026 -1.859

-1.222** 0.306 -7.187

-0.001 0.001 -0.252

-0.044* 0.026 -1.723

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.004 0.004 -0.836

0 0 0

ITA

-0.004 0.004 -0.907

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.127* 0.073 -4.144

-0.003 0.004 -0.756

-1.221** 0.306 -6.912

0 0.001 -0.396

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.003 0.004 -0.756

0 0 0

NTH

-0.045* 0.028 -2.066

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.004 0.005 -0.974

-0.044* 0.026 -1.723

0 0

-0.132

-1.222** 0.307 -7.253

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.044* 0.026 -1.723

0 0 0

NOR

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

-1.225** 0.307 -7.954

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

0 0 0

0 0 0

SWE

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.067* 0.04

-2.958

-1.225** 0.307 -7.954

0 0 0

0 0 0

GBR

-0.045* 0.027 -2.013

0 0 0

0 0 0

-0.044* 0.026 -1.859

-0.004 0.004 -0.836

-0.001 0.001 -0.252

-0.044* 0.026 -1.723

0 0 0

0 0 0

-1.222** 0.306 -7.187

0 0 0

USA

0 0 0

-0.128* 0.074 -4.876

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 0

-1.231** 0.309 -8.994

NOTES: The cell entries report the effect of a one-unit increase in the column country’s level of structural unemployment on the row country’s capital-tax rate. The first number reported in each cell is the estimated short-run effect (direct effect plus spatial feedback). The second number is that estimate’s standard error. The final number is the estimated long-run steady-steady effect. Australia and Japan are excluded because they have no neighbors in the sample. **Significant at the5% Level; *Significant at the 10% Level.

Page 43: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 4 of 7

Figure 1: Capital-Tax Policy Reaction-Functions

Page 44: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 5 of 7

Figure 2: Map of First-Period and Long-Run-Steady-State Effects of Permanent 1-Unit Increase in German Structural Unemployment on Capital-Tax Rates across the Sample

Page 45: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 6 of 7

Figure 3: Spatio-Temporal Effects on the German Capital-Tax-Rate from a Permanent One-Unit Counterfactual Positive Shock to Structural Unemployment in Germany (with a 90% C.I.)

-2

-1.8

-1.6

-1.4

-1.2

-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15

Cumulative 15-Period Effect: -6.523

Page 46: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

Tables & Figures: Page 7 of 7

Figure 4: Spatio-Temporal Effects on the French Capital-Tax-Rate from a Permanent One-Unit Counterfactual Positive Shock to Structural Unemployment in Germany (with a 90% C.I.)

-0.2

-0.15

-0.1

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15

Cumulative 15-Period Effect: -.943

Page 47: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 1 of 5

NOTES 1 Conceptually, the terms diffusion and interdependence seem subtly distinct in some literatures and

synonymous in others. The concepts overlap, and care in making and maintaining distinctions is not

always evident. For us here, interdependence will refer to contexts in which the outcomes of interest

(i.e., dependent variables) in some units of analysis (e.g., countries) directly affect outcomes in

others. Such interdependence may arise by myriad mechanisms, some of which must involve direct

contact between the units involved (or of elements therein, e.g., citizens of countries) but others do

not necessarily. Economic competition, e.g., does not require direct exchange between units to

induce interdependence. Diffusion here will refer to the patterns and paths across space (and usually

time) by which outcomes spread across units. It, too, may occur by many mechanisms, but patterns

of spatial diffusion may appear without any direct effect from outcomes in some units to those in

others, perhaps via spatial correlation in domestic or exogenous-external conditions affecting units.

Distinguishing these possibilities is the essence of Galton’s Problem (and ours). 2 A web appendix (www.umich.edu/~franzese/Publications.html) gives fuller reference lists for the

literatures developing empirical spatial-analysis and applying spatial interdependence in substantive

contexts. It also expands technical presentation of the methodological issues presented here. 3 At least from Crain 1966 and Walker 1969 through Gray 1973, Caldiera 1985, and Berry 1994 to

Boehmke & Witmer 2004 and Shipan & Volden 2006 (see note 2). 4 E.g., Schneider& Ingram 1988 to Meseguer 2004 and Braun& Gilardi 2006 (see note 2). 5 E.g., Huckfeldt & Sprague 1991 to Lacombe & Shaughnessy 2007 (see note 2). 6 E.g., Shin & Agnew 2002 to Kayser 2007 (see note 2). 7 E.g., Goldenberg et al. 1986 to Cho & Gimpel 2007 (see note 2). 8 E.g., Murdoch & Sandler 2004 to Gleditsch 2007 (see note 2). 9 Huckfeldt & Sprague (1993) review the mammoth literature on contextual effects in political

behavior, much of which highlights interdependence. See, e.g., Straits 1990, O’Loughlin et al 1994,

Huckfeldt et al 2005, Cho & Rudolph 2007 (see note 2). 10 E.g., from McAdam & Rucht 1993 to Swaroop & Morenoff 2006 (see note 2). 11 At least from Eising 2002 to Brune & Guisinger 2007 (see note 2).

Page 48: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 2 of 5

12 Indeed, quite probably: All of International Politics…, as Gleditsch’s (2002) title has it. 13 To our own list (Franzese & Hays 2003, 2006b, 2007ab, 2008a), we could easily add many dozens

more, e.g., from Genschel 2002 to Mukherjee & Singer 2007 (see note 2). 14 What is “learned” may be objective or subjective, true/correct or false/incorrect, and may regard

politics, economics, sociology, or any other aspect of the options that shapes their appeal to actors. 15 To find i’s optimal policy, maximize Wi with respect to pi, taking pj as given (fixed); i.e., set

0i

iW

p∂

∂ = , and solve for pi* as a function of pj. (Then verify that the second derivative is negative).

16 We eschew the terms race to the bottom (or top) and convergence because these competitive races

need not foster convergence to top, bottom, or mean, and could spur divergence (see below and, for

related further discussion of the observable regarding convergence, Plümper & Schneider 2006). 17 Unskilled labor is usually relatively mobile within (national) jurisdictions but highly immobile

across borders, especially those delineating strongly differentiated ethno-linguistic, religio-cultural

societies. Some skilled-labor works in highly specialized activities, limiting mobility of any kind;

other types, some human capitalists, e.g., may be relatively mobile across jurisdictions. 18 See Franzese (2003) for a more-complete review of Swank (2002). Again, however, Swank’s later

work (2006) and our own (2003, 2004, 2006a, 2007ab and below) properly specifies the effect of

globalization on tax rates as based in interdependence, modifying these conclusions considerably,

finding much stronger evidence for constraint on domestic autonomy from capital mobility. 19 Moreover, such competitive races would unfold regardless and independent of the efficiency of

those tax systems or of the public policies they support, and zero offers no inherent bottom to these

tax-cut races. In the competition for liquid portfolio-capital specifically, governments always have

incentives to cut taxes further, perhaps deep into subsidy; only their abilities to tax other less liquid

and/or mobile assets and to borrow limit (in internationally interdependent manner) these races. 20 These reaction-functions could slope positively or negatively because, while higher foreign tax-

rates lure capital into the domestic economy, the increased tax-base may allow domestic

policymakers to lower rates or, instead, to raise rates given the reduced elasticity of this base. 21 In later statistical analyses, the stochastic component, εit, might be allowed to exhibit spatial

Page 49: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 3 of 5

correlation, but this correlation would be treated as nuisance either to be corrected by Parks’ FGLS

procedure or, post-Beck-&-Katz (1995, 1996), to require adjustment to standard-errors (PCSE). 22 Again, the random component, εit, may exhibit spatial correlation—i.e., spatial correlation distinct

from that induced by exposure to the common shocks—but such correlation was treated as nuisance

to be ‘corrected’ by Parks procedure (FGLS) or, later, to require adjusted standard-errors (PCSE). 23 Differencing (in)dependent variable(s) thusly controls for global conditions in that (those) variable

but constrains coefficient(s) to be -1 (minus those on corresponding domestic independent variables). 24 Kronecker product, ⊗d s , multiplies the entire kdx1 vector of domestic factors, d, with each term

of the ksx1 vector of exogenous-external shocks, s, yielding a (kdks)x1 vector of interactions with

coefficients, sdβ . This is the most-general linear-interactive expression of context-conditionality. 25 Domestic institutional, structural, or contextual factors might include union density, industrial

structure, or electoral competitiveness. Exogenous-external conditions might include technological,

shipping, or financial progress. 26 Once again, any spatial correlation distinct from that induced by the context-conditioned responses

to common shocks was relegated to FGLS or PCSE corrections. In some of these empirical models,

controls for common shocks or other conditions abroad include dependent-variable conditions

abroad. However, these spatial lags are seen solely as nuisance controls proxying for exogenous-

external conditions, and their implied interdependence and spatial dynamics are unnoticed. 27 One could also allow spatial error-correlation to remain for address by FGLS or PCSE strategies,

but optimal here as previously will be to model interdependence and correlation directly if possible. 28 Sir Francis Galton (1889), commenting on a presentation (in 1888) by Sir Edward Tylor to the

Royal Anthropological Society in which Tylor suggested a causal correlation of societal complexity

to certain marriage and heritance customs, argued that these customs could not be viewed as

independent outcomes until the possibility that they “had derived from a common source, so that

they were duplicate copies of the same original” was rejected. The web appendix elaborates. 29 Methodologically, spatial-statistics and spatial-econometrics approaches to spatial analysis differ

(Anselin 2006). Crudely, and perhaps unfairly, the distinction corresponds to nuisance vs. substance

Page 50: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 4 of 5

and spatial-correlation vs. spatial-interdependence. The web appendix elaborates (see note 2). 30 Nonrectangular or missing data are manageable, but assuming full-rectangularity eases exposition. 31 In detail, for non-time-varying interdependence-patterns, this W matrix can be expressed as a

Kronecker product (see note 24) of a ×T T identity matrix and the ×N N weights matrix ( )T N⊗I W ,

with the elements wij of WN reflecting the relative connectivity from unit j to i as described above. 32 Alternative distributions of ε are possible but add complication without illumination. 33 Again, qualitative strategies that failed to consider interdependence or that considered it but failed

to redress properly the simultaneity of the observed phenomena would suffer the same biases. 34 Interest in strategies for parameterizing W in estimable models like (8) is great, but the literature

has offered little progress to date. 35 See especially Franzese & Hays (2007c, 2008a) regarding S-ML estimation; these correct some

misleading preliminary conclusions from the earlier work on that estimator. 36 The web appendix and previous work (Franzese & Hays 2004, 2006a, 2007cd, 2008ab) elaborate. 37 LeSage’s MatLab code is available at www.spatial-econometrics.com. One crucial correction: line

183 of sar.m references the wrong element of the variance-covariance matrix as the variance of ρ .

Our data and MatLab code for replication, our prototype Stata code, and our Excel spreadsheets are

available at www.umich.edu/~franzese/Publications under the respective articles, including this one. 38 Elhorst (2001:128) shows the likelihood function for the spatio-temporal lag model retains the bias

even in this best case if the first observation is stochastic (if initial conditions are random rather than

fixed across repeated samples). Franzese & Hays (2006a, 2007c, 2008ab) elaborate. (See note 2.) 39 This adds to arguments in note 43 favoring a geographic-proximity basis for W for our purposes. 40 E.g., the familiar linear-interaction models are explicitly nonlinear in variables though linear-

additive in parameters; logit/probit models are explicitly nonlinear in variables and parameters; and

temporally or spatially dynamic models are implicitly nonlinear in parameters and variables. 41 Assuming row-standardized W, spatio-temporal stationarity requires | | 1ϕ ρ+ < (see note 2). 42 Given stationarity, the LRSS of any temporary shock is zero. Conceptually useful is to decompose

ε into fixed η plus stochastic γt and then to consider permanent shocks to ε as occurring in η.

Page 51: Interdependence in Comparative Politics: Substance, Theory

Franzese & Hays Interdependence in Comparative Politics

References: Page 5 of 5

43 We do not intend by these arguments to suggest alternative connectivity matrices, based on dyadic

FDI, trade, or financial flows, or on similarity or diversity in flows to third parties or in production,

export/import, or asset/liability profiles, might not also capture important bases on which countries

compete for capital. These seem substantively quite likely. Moreover, from an expository view, they

would have better-illustrated two key points: (1) connectivity matrices must be soundly theoretically

motivated, precisely measured, and substantively powerful, especially since empirical analyses tend

to understate spatial interdependence when spatial model-components are relatively poorly specified,

and (2) proximity/connectivity of units, and so W, need neither be symmetric nor geographically

determined. (Our row-standardized contiguity-matrices are substantively motivated, etc., as argued

in the text, and asymmetric, because bordering i and j can have differing numbers of other bordering

units, but these features may be less obvious.) However, as noted, recent research finds contiguity

and proximity to be extremely strong determinants of who competed with whom for capital; Swank

(2006) already explored some of these alternatives with rather discouraging, although inconclusive,

results; and wij based on economic transactions, flows (FDI, trade, financial) or stocks (production,

export/import, asset-portfolio profiles) are especially likely to be endogenous to fiscal policy. 44 The included unit and period fixed-effects proved necessary for stationarity (see note 41). 45 First-order spatial-effects incur to neighbors, including all feedback through all units; second-

order spatial-effects would refer to the effects on neighbors’ neighbors (e.g., of Germany on Italy).