29
Perspectives on Participation in Economic Policy Reform in Africa Derick W. Brinkerhoff, with assistance from Nicolas P. Kulibaba This article examines two questions regarding participation in economic policy reform in Africa: how do the circumstances surrounding participation and the ways it occurs influence the economic policy reform process, and can changes to enhance participation lead to improved policy outcomes? The general findings are, first, that the pattern of participation is an important variable in the policy reform process, but that its effects on reform outcomes are strongly mediated by African political and governance factors. Second, increased participation appears to enhance prospects for sustainable reform outcomes, though the weak capacity and responsiveness of the state and the incipient nature of civil society's associational infrastructure in much of Africa limit opportuni- ties for institutionalizing participation. It is important to be aware of participation's limits as well as its potential contributions to economic policy reform in the context of political liberalization, and to recognize the long-term nature of the transition to new modes of state-society cooperation. S ince the 1980s, two major trends have recast the roles of national governments and their citizens: the shift to open-market economies and the move toward Derick W. Brinkerhoff, a senior social scientist with Abt Associates Inc., is research director for the Implementing Policy Change Project, funded by the U.S. Agency for International Development, and is an adjunct faculty member at Johns Hopkins University, School of Advanced International Studies. He has worked extensively in Africa and Haiti on policy, management, and institutional issues. Prior to joining Abt, he spent ten years at the University of Maryland's International Development Manage- ment Center. Dr. Brinkerhoff has published widely, including five books and numerous articles and book chapters. His latest publication is an edited special issue of World Development (Vol. 24, No. 9) devoted to policy implementation. He holds an Ed.D. from Harvard University and an M.Admin. from the University of California, Riverside. His current research focuses on government-NGO partnerships for policy reform. Nicolas P. Kulibaba is a senior policy analyst with Abt Associates Inc. He has wide experience in Africa in the livestock, export promotion, enterprise credit, and rural development sectors. He has also conducted political risk assessments in Africa and the Caribbean for a variety of multinational firms. Mr. Kulibaba holds a Diploma in social anthropology from Oxford University, Oxford, England. Correspondence address for both authors: Abt Associates Inc., 4800 Montgomery Lane #600, Bethesda, MD 20814 USA. Studies in Comparative International Development, Fall 1996, Vol. 31, No. 3, 123-151.

Perspectives on participation in economic policy reform in Africa

  • Upload
    rti

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Perspectives on Participation in Economic Policy Reform in Africa

Derick W. Brinkerhoff, with assistance from Nicolas P. Kulibaba

This article examines two questions regarding participation in economic policy reform in Africa: how do the circumstances surrounding participation and the ways it occurs influence the economic policy reform process, and can changes to enhance participation lead to improved policy outcomes? The general findings are, first, that the pattern of participation is an important variable in the policy reform process, but that its effects on reform outcomes are strongly mediated by African political and governance factors. Second, increased participation appears to enhance prospects for sustainable reform outcomes, though the weak capacity and responsiveness of the state and the incipient nature of civil society's associational infrastructure in much of Africa limit opportuni- ties for institutionalizing participation. It is important to be aware of participation's limits as well as its potential contributions to economic policy reform in the context of political liberalization, and to recognize the long-term nature of the transition to new modes of state-society cooperation.

S i nce the 1980s, t w o m a j o r t r ends h a v e r eca s t the ro les o f n a t i o n a l g o v e r n m e n t s

a n d the i r c i t i zens : the shi f t to o p e n - m a r k e t e c o n o m i e s and the m o v e t o w a r d

Derick W. Brinkerhoff, a senior social scientist with Abt Associates Inc., is research director for the Implementing Policy Change Project, funded by the U.S. Agency for International Development, and is an adjunct faculty member at Johns Hopkins University, School of Advanced International Studies. He has worked extensively in Africa and Haiti on policy, management, and institutional issues. Prior to joining Abt, he spent ten years at the University of Maryland's International Development Manage- ment Center. Dr. Brinkerhoff has published widely, including five books and numerous articles and book chapters. His latest publication is an edited special issue of World Development (Vol. 24, No. 9) devoted to policy implementation. He holds an Ed.D. from Harvard University and an M.Admin. from the University of California, Riverside. His current research focuses on government-NGO partnerships for policy reform. Nicolas P. Kulibaba is a senior policy analyst with Abt Associates Inc. He has wide experience in Africa in the livestock, export promotion, enterprise credit, and rural development sectors. He has also conducted political risk assessments in Africa and the Caribbean for a variety of multinational firms. Mr. Kulibaba holds a Diploma in social anthropology from Oxford University, Oxford, England. Correspondence address for both authors: Abt Associates Inc., 4800 Montgomery Lane #600, Bethesda, MD 20814 USA.

Studies in Comparative International Development, Fall 1996, Vol. 31, No. 3, 123-151.

124 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

democratization. The linkages between the two, and whether they are synergistic or antagonistic, have been the subject of much attention worldwide.1 For developing countries the debate is especially critical, because it influences the policy and pro- gram conditionalities associated with international financial resource flows. In com- parison to the rest of the developing world, the 1980s for Africa have been termed a "lost decade," where both rural and urban populations ended up worse off by 1990 than ten years earlier (World Bank 1994a, 1989; Chole 1989). In the 1990s, though, the trends toward increased economic and political liberalization have spread across the continent, and the debate on the nature of the linkages between economic reform and political liberalization has been taken up in the African context. An issue central to both trends is participation, which has enjoyed something of a policy renaissance over the past several years. 2 This article reviews the literature that addresses participation in economic policy reform in Africa. It explores two ques- tions: how do the circumstances surrounding participation and the ways it occurs influence the economic policy reform process and can changes to enhance participa- tion lead to improved policy outcomes?

Key Issues

Embedded within these questions lies an array of issues of direct concern both to international donors and African governments. From the viewpoint of the interna- tional donor community, two types of issues emerge regarding participation. The first is an analytic problem: can the relationships between participation and various types of economic policy reform be sufficiently understood and unpacked so that more effective policy prescriptions and strategies can be developed? The second is an operational one: how can donors shape, influence, and reinforce participatory processes and mechanisms so as to increase the sustainability and impact of eco- nomic reforms? Of major debate is the extent to which donors should focus on helping African governments to work better, on strengthening civil society, or on both. Donors have the longest experience in institutional development (Israel 1987). Increasingly, however, they have turned attention to civil society, which as Dia- mond defines it, refers to formal and informal groups of "citizens acting collectively in a public sphere to express their interests, passions, and ideas, exchange informa- tion, achieve mutual goals, make demands on the state, and hold state officials accountable" (1994, 5). 3 The notion here is that rather than emphasizing institu- tional supply, an approach that strengthens interest groups' ability to demand better government performance can yield fruitful results (see Goldsmith 1993).

Economic policy reform, public sector capacity-building, and the strengthening of civil society all converge in the current donor focus on governance. As defined by the World Bank (1992 1994b), governance has four components: efficient public sector management, accountability, a supportive legal framework, and transparent information flows. 4 Governance arrangements constrain and shape the possibilities for participation, and thus are important mediating factors in the links between participation and policy outcomes. In turn, broadbased participation is integral to

Brinkerhoff and Kdibaba 125

good governance; without it, accountability turns to insularity, legal frameworks remain paper exercises, and transparency becomes opaque (see Hyden 1992; Jeffries 1993; Landell-Mills 1992).

From the viewpoint of African governments, the participation issues of greatest concern are the practical, operational ones. They too are concerned with keeping reforms on track, improving governance capacity, and addressing the demands of civil society, but with an immediacy that external assistance providers do not face (Fitzgerald et al. 1995; Mutahaba et al. 1993; Picard and Garrity 1994). Young captures this point in his discussion of the necessity of African governments to deal with the "imperative of democratization" where responding to pressures to liberal- ize, both economically and politically, is "no longer an option, but an obligation" (1994, 230). As the trajectory of economic reform moves from the earlier stages of stabilization, usually managed by a small team of technocrats, to liberalization and, ultimately, long-haul consolidation, where much larger numbers of actors are in- volved, African decision-makers and policy managers increasingly face the require- ment of building coalitions and managing consensus (Haggard and Kaufman 1994; Thomas and Grindle 1990). These tasks are intimately bound up with issues of participation. For example, how can commitment to reform be created and sustained among interest groups? How can the destabilizing effects of reform and the con- flicts they generate be coped with, and how can the losers in the reform process be compensated or coopted?

Defining Participation

Participation is an extremely broad concept, one that has over the years enjoyed what Cohen and Uphoff, writing over fifteen years ago, called "popularity without clarity" (1980). That characterization still applies today, with perhaps even more salience than ever on the African continent as the trend toward more open forms of government and an expanded role for civil society continues to grow. International assistance agencies, academics, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), and de- veloping country counterparts have debated and discussed the definitions, roles, aims, and utility of participation in various fora over the years (see Nagle 1991). In general, participation conveys images of involvement, inclusion, and engagement; it invokes notions of joining in, of taking part. Our perspective on participation seeks to detail its parameters across a range of situations rather than advance a definition that tries to establish a clear line between what is, or is not, participation. This approach avoids attempting a specific definition of participation, which can lead to muddy, unresolvable debates over whether a specific instance of participation is "authentic" and "genuine" (and therefore good), or "false" and "invalid" (bad).

We define participation along three dimensions that accommodate a range of activities, actors, and actions. This framework adapts earlier work done on rural development project participation (Cohen and Uphoff 1980) to the larger sphere of policy reform. The answers to three questions provide participation's defining fea- tures: participation in what? by whom? and how?

126 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

The "what" question addresses the kind of participation being undertaken or con- sidered. The kinds of participation of major concern for our purposes relate to the sequential steps in the policy process. These are participation in policy: analysis. design and adoption, implementation, and monitoring and evaluation. Taken to- gether, these kinds of participation comprise a policy reform cycle, which, over the life of a given policy reform, can go through several iterations, with a variety of interactive feedback loops among, and refinements in, each of the steps. In the real world the policy process is never unilinear.

Looking at who participates in economic policy reform, the framework differenti- ates participants into several categories. External participants include international donor agencies, both multilateral and bilateral and technical assistance providers. In-country participants can be divided into national government personnel, local government staff, private sector actors, NGOs, various interest groups at different levels (professional associations, unions, religious groups, students, political parties, etc.), and local residents (merchants, traders, farmers, women, laborers). Of concern for this dimension of the framework is specification of the interests of each category of actors, the resources they bring to the policy process, their motivation to use those resources, and their likely impacts. Determination of winners and losers is key.

The "how" dimension addresses a number of issues that seek to clarify the quali- tative aspect of participation. These issues are strongly associated with the sustainability of the policy reform. The framework looks at the source of initiative for participation such as: from an external donor agency or some domestic constitu- ency, from the center or the grass-roots, from a broad set of actors or a single interest group. The incentives for participation are important; is participation volun- tary, induced, or coerced? Another critical qualitative issue relates to the types of institutional structures used for participation (formal or informal, public or private, strong or weak, markets or hierarchies). The extent of participation deals with the time demands, the number and range of actors and activities involved, and the limits imposed. Finally, the "how" dimension considers the degree of empowerment asso- ciated with participation. This aspect is often singled out as the most important by many observers, and is the most frequently cited feature distinguishing whether participation is "genuine" or not.

Participation in Economic Policy Reform in Africa

The literature on participation in policy reform falls into three broad categories. 5 The first category, technical economic performance perspectives, contains analysis of structural adjustment programs, and focuses on how participation fosters or im- pedes appropriate policy choice and achievement of economic performance targets. Sources include case studies of individual country performance with policy reforms and multi-country cross-case analyses (Abbott 1993; Berg 1990; Husain and Faraqee 1994; Lieberson 1991; Mills 1989; Thomas et al. 1991; Vondal 1989; Zulu and Nsouli 1985). This category's orientation to participation concentrates on its contri- bution to getting the policies right.

Brinkerhoff and Kdibaba 127

The second category, political economy, contains several streams. A large litera- ture addresses the nature and role of the state and the implications for participation (Boye 1993; Callaghy 1990; Lemarchand 1992; Sahn and Sarris 1992; Shaw 1993; van de Walle 1994). Numerous authors analyze the impacts of interest groups on policy outcomes (e.g., Gulhati 1990a and 1990b; Krueger 1993; Skalne 1993; Toye 1992; Widner 1993, 1994), including individual country cases (e.g., Chazan 1983; Herbst 1993; and Rothchild 1991 on Ghana; Bates and Collier 1992; and Kydd 1989 on Zambia; Kiondo 1989 on Tanzania). Other authors look at NGOs and the private sector (Bienen and Waterbury 1989; Bratton 1989b and 1990; Shaw 1990) and at participation of civil society in the policy process (Harbeson et al. 1994; Migdal 1988. Rothchild and Chazan 1988; Wunsch and Olowu 1990). Another stream contains authors who see participation in terms of the relative power distri- butions between the international financial institutions and individual countries (Fearon 1988; Good 1989; Schoenholtz 1987). A substream of African analysts focuses on the roots of political economy in indigenous cultural patterns and prac- tices (Ake 1990; Ayittey 1990 and 1991; Etounga-Manguelle 1991; Heilbrunn 1993; Tadesse 1992). Literature in this category can be characterized as emphasizing participation' s place in getting the politics of policy reform right.

The third literature category looks at the institutional and management dimensions of participation and policy reform. Major emphases here are on institutional capac- ity, both as a constraint to participation in the policy process and as an area for technical assistance (Fitzgerald et al. 1995; Frischtak 1994; Hirschmann 1993; Lamb 1987; Sutton 1987); civil service reform and the role of bureaucrats in policy change (Brown 1989; Garvey 1991; Leonard 1991; Montgomery 1988); management tools and techniques that can help deal with interest groups (Brinkerhoff 1991; Crosby 1992a and 1992b; Grindle and Thomas 1990; Robinson 1990; White 1990a and 1990b); and the institutional requirements for effective participation of civil society in policy reform (Bratton 1989a; Hyden 1990; Talbott 1990). African public admin- istration specialists constitute a sub-stream of literature in this category (Balogun and Mutahaba 1989; Kiggundu 1989; Mutahaba et al. 1993; Picard and Garrity 1994). The viewpoint here can be summed up as concentrating on linking who participates and how to get the institutions right for effective policy reform.

What Kind of Participation?

Participation in policy analysis and design in general has been relatively restricted by both weak African policy analytic capacity and lack of demand. Numerous sources cite the low level of technical analytic skills as an important constraint to African participation in policy dialogue (Commonwealth Secretariat 1990; Gulhati 1990b; McCleary 1991; Mutahaba and Balogun 1992; Nunberg 1990; Paul 1990; Sutton 1987). The capacity constraint diminished during the 1980s as a result of training and increased experience (World Bank 1991), but indigenous demand for policy analysis remains limited. The political economy literature notes that in many cases African leaders have been little interested in technical arguments for or against

128 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

policies, being more concerned with regime maintenance and political survival (Bienen 1993; Crook 1990; Evans 1992; Hyden 1992). This factor is also mentioned in explaining why leaders pursued economically irrational policies in the first place. In authoritarian regimes, the conduct of independent, critical policy analysis has been discouraged, thus limiting the growth of independent analytic capacity. In- creasing indigenous demand for policy analysis is seen as one way to increase African ownership for policy reform (World Bank 1991; Johnson and Wasty 1993).

Regarding policy design/adoption, the impact of donor procedures and timetables is frequently noted (McCleary 1991; Nelson 1990). The design process is usually conducted by a small technical team and a closed circle of national actors (Gulhati 1990b). Institutional constraints limit African technocrats' effective role in the pro- cess (Gulhati 1990a; Mutahaba and Balogun 1992). In many countries, decision- makers have seen little need to consult elements of civil society beyond symbolic, tightly managed opportunities for popular ratification of policy choices already made, although political liberalization is modifying this pattern somewhat (Hyden and Bratton 1992; Nyang'oro and Shaw 1992). However, policy designs that build political support for reform measures are more successful than those that do not (Corbo and Fischer 1990; White 1990a and 1990b). Participation in policy design is expanding via a range of consultative mechanisms such as: national conferences (Heilbrunn 1993: Sall 1989). social marketing (Corbo and Fischer 1990). involve- ment in polls and surveys (Atherton et al. 1992; Monga 1994b; Vondal 1989). Sources agree that participation is more likely in democratizing countries (Hyden and Bratton 1992). Botswana is cited as exemplary in this regard; Molutsi and Holm (1992, 82) note that "top officials have come to believe that government programs work better if the public can be induced to participate.. , in governing processes. The Government has sought to obtain popular consent for specific programs through public consultations" (see also Picard 1987; Wiseman 1990).

All the streams of literature stress participation in implementation as having the most influence on the achievement or failure of policy objectives. The recognition that, in practice, policy implementation is not simply a mechanical process of carry- ing out measures decided upon previously is in large part responsible for the blur- ring of the boundaries between the steps in the linear policy process model and its recasting in terms of an interactive, multidirectional frame (Brinkerhoff 1991; Grindle and Thomas 1991; Kulibaba and Rielly 1993; Thomas and Grindle 1990; White 1990a and 1990c). Participation in policy implementation can be divided into two categories: participation by implementing agents and by groups that are the target of reforms. Regarding the former, the literature notes the issues of capacity, civil service reform, and the need for a stronger state apparatus to implement policies even if the role of the state in economic activity is reduced (Berg 1990; Callaghy 1990; Nunberg 1990; Silverman 1996). 6 State agents are often seen as obstacles to policy implementation, viewed as (at best) captives of vested interests, or (at worst) the predatory personification of the abusive state apparatus, driven by the desire to maintain elite control over public resources for rentseeking and patronage purposes (Rothchild and Chazan 1988; Garvey 199l; Lemarchand 1992). But, as Grindle points out (1991), bureaucrats are not always simply the sum of the preferences of

Brlnkerhoff and Kdibaba 129

their strongest patrons/lobbies; some are sincerely interested in reform, as Leonard (1991) illustrates in his study of the careers of four African civil servants.

Regarding participation by reform targets, their impact is greater in long-haul reforms than stroke-of-pen ones (Healy and Robinson 1992; Nelson 1989; Bienen and Waterbury 1989; CSIS 1992). Successful implementation over time highlights the importance of coalition-building among key stakeholders. Hawkins (1991), for example, credits the failure to build such coalitions as a major contributor to the demise of Zambia's economic reform program under Kaunda (Bates and Collier 1992; Callaghy 1990; Gulhati 1989). Participation here is of two types: voice and exit (Hirschman 1969). 7 Formal voice options are: participation in national confer- ences, rallies, and other organized fora (Bratton and van de Walle 1992; Ouane 1990); policy/program review committees (USAID n.d.); information dissemination campaigns and/or the media (West and Fair 1993); through NGOs and other volun- tary associations (Widner and van der Veen 1993). Informal voice includes: sponta- neous protests, rumor campaigns, one-on-one meetings with officials. Exit reflects such actions as: withholding support, non-participation in services or policy benefits (Finsterbusch and Van Wicklin 1987), boycotts, retreat into the informal sector (MacGaffey et al. 1991), evasion of policy provisions through bribery and side-payments (Bates and Krueger 1993), and migration (Kom 1993).

Participation in policy monitoring and evaluation (M&E) is relatively limited. There is not much M&E in inward-looking public sector agencies, and thus M&E capacity needs to be developed (Brinkerhoff 1991; Kiggundu 1989; Wiesner 1993; White 1990a). Participation in policy impact surveys and reviews is one way of involving target groups in M&E (Atherton et al. 1992). Civil society can serve an important governance function here as an independent watchdog; this is a role for NGOs, the media, and universities (see Charlick 1992; Fowler 1991 ; Harbeson et al. 1994; Wedelt 1986; World Bank 1994b).

Who Participates?

The participation of national government personnel is critical, since they are frequently the major actors in the policy process (Evans 1992; Rondinelli and Mont- gomery 1990). Sources note their capacity to subvert policies, the fact that bureau- crats are often beholden to special interests (Callaghy 1989; Johnson and Wasty 1993), and the weak institutional structures national staff operate within (see Sahn and Sarris 1992; Wunsch and Olowu 1990). International donor agencies are also key players, and their participation is critical to initiating reforms and determining reform targets and conditionalities (Beckman 1992; Healey and Robinson 1992; Nelson 1990). The private sector is often the target of reform efforts (Bienen 1990; Young 1991). The sector falls into two groups: formal and informal. The former is small, urban, male, and protected by close links to state (Gordon 1991). The latter is large and rural, contains many women, participates minimally in the policy process, but tends to be responsive to policy changes (Gladwin 1991; Kulibaba 1993a and 1993b, Lele 1986).

130 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

The importance of the urban middle class as participants in policy reform is noted by various sources (Haggard and Kaufman 1992; Widner 1994). In many African countries the members of this group are the most powerful, and most vocal constitu- encies for economic and political reforms (Bratton and van de Walle 1992). Studies of the impacts of economic stabilization and structural adjustment confirm that in many cases the middle class, which includes civil servants and students, has suf- fered greater declines in income and welfare as a result of reforms than rural residents (Sahn and Sarris, 1992; Shaw 1993). The derailment of Zambia's adjust- ment program is a widely cited cautionary tale of the need for government to take into account the urban middle class in pushing reforms ahead (Bates and Collier 1992; Gulhati 1989; Hawkins 1991; Kydd 1989). The participation of urban middle class interest groups in reform-minded coalitions is critical to the maintenance of government commitment to reforms, and to the ultimate success of long-haul liber- alization programs (Johnston and Wasty 1993; Nelson 1989; Rothchild and Foley 1988; Toye 1992).

NGOs are the subject of a large literature (see Edwards and Hulme 1992). They are important as interest aggregators, and play a mediating role between the state and individuals (Clark 1991; Fowler 1991; Shaw 1993). 8 International NGOs are a lobbying force, and operate in some African countries too. Besides NGOs, African civil society contains other, diverse associational groups (Bratton 1989a; Harbeson et al. 1994). Though not recognized by the state, there is a significant amount of informal participation by people in a wide range of horizontal voluntary associa- tions (Chazan 1992b). Bates' now classic study (1981) points out the fallacy of the assumption that rural Africans were largely quiescent and disengaged from policy-making due to their geographical dispersion, low socioeconomic status and the rigors of agrarian life. He argues that the extent of agrarian organization was a consequence of whether there were large farmers with a special stake in more favorable policy; whether the loyalty of larger, more militant farmers could be co-opted through selective administration of subsidies, and whether or how much heads of state and political elites derived personal income or support from rural constituencies (see also Bates 1988). Similar conclusions can be drawn about other interest groups, underlining the fact that absent opportunities for formal participa- tion in the policy process, stakeholders devise their own subtle yet effective means of exerting influence on policy outcomes. As Colboum (1989) notes, strategies of non-compliance (including foot dragging, feigned ignorance, false compliance, or sabotage) provide a means by which groups in civil society can "critique" policy, without drawing the wrath of the authorities (see also Ela 1992).

Experience with this kind of participation constitutes an important source of so- cial capital, which can be tapped for reform (Amrthier 1989; MacGaffey et al. 1991; cf. Putnam et al. 1993). With political liberalization, civil groups and the media are more vocal, putting pressure on African governments for change (Monga 1995, 1994a). Local residents, the poor, and other disenfranchised groups have very limited direct participation in reform (Ela 1992; Mikell 1989). The poor, however,

Brlnkerhoff and Kulibaba 131

are a topic of discussion by others regarding the impacts of adjustment on their well-being (Jolly 1988; Lele 1986 and 1990; Sahn 1990; Sarris 1990; Taube 1993).

The configuration of who outside of government participates in policy reform is strongly influenced by the broader political system in a particular country. The role and scope of interest groups, whether in the private sector or civil society, differ considerably under authoritarian, democratic, transitional, or collapsed systems (Rothchild and Foley 1988; Young 1994; Zartman 1994). African governments in many countries are searching for ways of creating an enabling environment that fosters greater interest group participation, in both the political and economic spheres (Hyden 1990; Rothchild 1994).

How Does Participation Take Place?

The impetus for reform is often donor-driven. The perceived need for reform by African leadership is linked to crisis situations, where the urge to reform develops as a function of the elimination of other options (Grindle and Thomas 199 I; Krueger 1993; Kulibaba and Rielly 1993; Mosely et al. 1991). Political liberalization in many countries, however, is accompanied by popular demand for economic liberal- ization, so it is too simple to say that reforms have been forced on Africa by donors. In fact, the actual process of negotiating and implementing reforms involves a large degree of joint initiation of proposals and counterproposals (Berg 1990, 1991; Brinkerhoff and Morgan 1989; White 1990c).

Incentives for participation are related to the classic interest-maximization prin- ciple, where the motivation to participate is a function of groups seeking to advance their interests (Liddle 1992). The uncertainty and complexity of policies, though, can make identification of interests difficult (Bates and Krueger, 1993). Key vari- ables, therefore, in determining incentives for participation are: a) how different groups perceive the policy and its impact on them, and b) how they define their interests as they relate to the policy and its impact. A common conclusion regarding adjustment policies and governments' ability to sustain commitment to measures agreed to is that reform costs are immediate and clearly hurt key constituencies while benefits are diffuse, uncertain, and take a long time to be realized (Bienen 1990; Johnson and Wasty 1993; van de WaUe 1994). Some authors suggest strate- gies for addressing this pattern of incentives. For example, based on the Zambian reform experience, Hawkins (1991) offers four possible strategies that could help to deal with winners and losers: repress opposition, appeal to patriotic sentiment, promote new constituencies among winners, and/or make short-term transfer pay- ments to loser groups.

Institutional structures for participation have traditionally been dominated by the state and a coterie of privileged elites, but governments are facing new demands for accountability and transparency from vocal civil society (Hyden 1992; Young 1994). Weak capacity constrains the effectiveness of the public sector, but a revised role for the state offers institutional space for civil groups to participate more broadly in reforms, for example, through NGOs and/or legally recognized local-level associa-

132 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

tions (Chazan 1992b; Rothchild and Chazan 1988; Widner and van der Veen 1993). The potential extent of broader participation is limited by policy type. More oppor- tunities exist in long-term reforms, such as privatization (Bienen and Waterbury 1989) or natural resources policy (Brinkerhoff 1995), than in what van de Walle (1994) calls "price-based policies" (e.g., exchange rates) where there is little scope for participation beyond a small team of donor and national technocrats in the finance ministry and the central bank. Haggard and Kaufman (1994) note that economic liberalization and consolidation policy reforms greatly expand the options for participation, in that successful outcomes depend upon the creation and mainte- nance of supportive coalitions of stakeholders.

Regarding the degree of empowerment available for participants in the reform process, popular protest is often cited (Monga 1995, 1994a), but this is not the only mechanism for voice. Other options include, for example, lobbying, policy dia- logue, and media campaigns, all of which can be used to bring pressure to bear on politicians and policy-makers. While visible and vocal outbursts in opposition to specific policy effects may cause governments to seek tactical policy adjustments in the short-term (Bratton and van de Walle 1992), long-term empowerment of groups to participate in the policy-making process in liberalized systems is strongly related to their ability to translate economic demands into political ones, something that the urban middle class is better positioned to do than the rural poor (Woods 1992). Bratton (1990, 89) states that the challenge for the 1990s is, "how can the poor majority reach the makers of public policy?" As mentioned above in the section on who participates, regime type strongly influences the degree of empowerment avail- able to citizens and interest groups (Widner 1994).

Dominant Themes in the Literature

As the above overview makes clear, the participation literature is vast and rela- tively diverse. This section singles out a set of topical areas that emerge from the literature as dominant themes and issues. These are grouped into three categories.

The Political Economy of the African State

The state provides the principal context in which participation occurs, determin- ing the kinds of contributions that the private sector and civil society can make to policy reform and implementation. 9 Initially, authoritarian regimes were thought to be more able to cope effectively with implementing unpopular economic stabiliza- tion measures. Numerous studies have investigated the link between regime type and reform success (Bates and Krueger 1993; Greenaway and Morrissey 1993; Haggard and Kaufman 1992; Lindenberg and Devarajan 1993; Sirowy and Inkeles 1990). However, they find no clear relationship between regime type and success in economic reform, although democratizing regimes offer more opportunities for par- ticipation in policy reform than do authoritarian ones (Widner 1994). Most par-

Brinkerhoff and Kelibaba 133

ticipation is largely informal, with interest groups able to influence policy decisions by petitioning "their" representatives in government to act in their favor.

Policy-making in this context is limited to a closed elite circle (Gulhati 1990b), is relatively arbitrary, and lacks the rationality and empirical content characteristic of technically based policymaking (Hyden 1992). This closed process creates a kind of "black market government," with parallel structures of persuasion and influence that guide economic policy, but which are neither publicly acknowledged nor formally sanctioned. Studies by Ziegler (1978), Pran (1983), Smith, Combeaud and Moutout (1990), and Smith and Glaser (1992) focus on the influence of private interests on policymakers, noting how the patterns of interlocking mutual interests create policy distortions that favor elite personal and commercial interests. Opening up the policy process is also difficult because the African state has traditionally guarded informa- tion jealously, but transparency is vital to policy debate and consensus-building for reform. In many countries, civil society's demand-making capacity is growing, thus some increases in transparency can be expected (Landell-Mills 1992; World Bank 1994b).

However, most studies conclude on a cautionary note regarding the prospects for significantly more participatory state-society relations. Africa's weak states have traditionally depended upon clientelist arrangements with elite groups for support and survival (Rothchild and Chazan 1988; Widner 1994; Wunsch and Olowu 1990). As Rothchild points out, broadbased cooperative links and collaborative norms between African governments and citizenry remain to be built (1994). The democ- ratizing measures countries have taken to date are but the first steps in a long process toward increased participation and democratic governance.

Donor Participation in Reform

Donor participation is strong, particularly in the analysis and design stages of reform, but good design of technical policy prescriptions is not enough (White 1990a). Reform success requires education and consensus-building, negotiation and compromise, and active reform "marketing" (Thomas et al. 1991; World Bank 1994a; Waterbury 1989). Donor procedures are cited as inhibiting country participa- tion in the policy reform process (Mosely et al. 1991; Toye 1992), although local officials and technicians can be valuable participants in reform design and initiation. This situation is changing for the better as some donors are modifying their prac- tices and procedures to incorporate participation more broadly and easily (Atwood 1993; Bhatnagar and Williams 1992; USAID n.d.; Vondal 1989; World Bank 1994c).

Policy-based aid is a mixed blessing for African governments (Winter 1984). The access to quick-disbursing financial mechanisms to meet emergency expenditures is desirable, but engages leaders in a process that risks dismantling the instruments that assure their power base (White 1990c). For the international financial institu- tions, the economic prescriptions of stabilization and adjustment are ostensibly apo- litical. Yet if those prescriptions are implemented, they are certain to have political outcomes (Cohen et al. 1985). This technical orientation, accompanied by the avow-

154 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

edly apolitical nature of reform prescription, often leaves donors without explicit strategies for dealing with the political reservations of African decision-makers. 1~ The problem of conflicting views and agenda can be further compounded by the absence from the negotiating table of key stakeholder groups whose compliance with or opposition to reform is ultimately critical (Brinkerhoff and Morgan 1989; Crosby 1992b). Country cases show elaborate strategies for non-compliance, raising issues about commitment to reform (Johnson and Wasty 1993; Kulibaba and Rielly 1993). Conditionality can induce initiation of reform, but is not an effective tool for enforcing compliance or sustaining change (Berg 1991; Hermann 1986; McCleary 1991; White 1990c). Interestingly, the reasons governments give for failing to meet conditionalities are often participation-related: the need for consultation with stake- holders, election calendars, democratization timetables, public unrest and insecurity, the need to train bureaucrats and other government agents, and the need to educate the public about reform rationale. Although such reasoning is often legitimate, it is also sometimes little more than game playing (Berg 1991).

Institutional Capacity for Participation in Policy Reform

The literature stresses the need for sufficient capacity on the part of the institu- tions involved in the policy process in order for participation to take place. This capacity is linked to: a) quality of leadership, b) capacity of the government bureau- cracy, and c) the nature of the interaction among leaders, bureaucrats, and external actors (Gulhati 1988). Regarding leadership, in Africa where systems governed by personal rule are more commonplace than other regions, leaders take on a particular importance. The absence of institutionalized checks and balances in the postcolonial state has allowed the African leader to control closely who has access to resources and decision-making (Adamolekun 1988; Obasanjo and d'Orville 1991). The role of national leaders stands out in several country cases of economic policy reform; for example, Rawlings' remarkable achievements in Ghana's economic recovery pro- duced one of the few success stories of adjustment in Africa (Chazan 1992a; Jeffries 1991). Malawi's Banda and the Ivory Coast's Houphouet-Boigny, on the other hand, held off deep institutional reform while preserving pro-business approaches to development (Harrigan 1991; Pryor 1990; Widner 1993). In Tanzania, Nyerere's charisma and commitment to African socialism created an ideological atmosphere that stifled progress toward market reforms, which only became possible upon his retirement (Bierman 1988; Campbell 1992; Kiondo 1989).

Although national leaders can create a favorable climate for reform, they are not the major actors in the day-to-day implementation of economic policy. Senior tech- nocrats are. If available from among this pool, a "policy champion" can enhance the chances of reform success by: organizing constituencies for reform, convincing leaders of the need for reform, overcoming bureaucratic barriers, and mitigating public outcry (Leonard 1991; Rielly 1993; Rondinelli and Montgomery 1990). Such superstar participants in the policy process are in short supply, however. Donors sometimes end up competing for the same pool of committed, technocratic talent to fulfill the policy champion role.

Brinkerhoff and Kulibaba 135

On the subject of public sector capacity, bureaucratic systems suffer from acute capacity weaknesses: inability to deliver even the most basic services, tendency of civil servants to extract rents and/or take second jobs as salaries slip below subsis- tence levels, inappropriate and ineffective organizations for managing public ser- vices, low personnel competence levels, and failure to use appropriate technologies and management techniques (Lamb 1987; Pinto 1994; Silverman 1996; Wunsch and Olowu 1990). On the one hand, these bureaucratic systems need to be strengthened; but economic stabilization measures often call for reductions in the civil service at the same time that ambitious structural adjustment programs impose new challenges on public sectors (Balogun and Mutahaba 1989; Frischtak 1994; Mutahaba et al. 1993; Picard and Garrity 1994).

Compounding the capacity problem is the fact that the number of participants in the economic policy reform process is large (Haggard and Kaufman 1994; Thomas and Grindle 1990; Toye 1992). For example, Oyugi (1994) illustrates this complex- ity in the case of policy implementation in Kenya; Ka and van de Walle (1994), writing about Senegal, credit the failure of the Diouf government to build a broad coalition with stalling the reform implementation process. Because of the interlinked nature of long-term reform measures, and the increasingly recognized importance of sequencing (Thomas et al. 1991; Haggard and Kaufman 1994), reform progress risks being limited by the capacity of the policy management network's weakest member(s). This situation can provoke a "snowball effect" of delays, where one missed deadline leads to a cascade of postponements, deferrals, and suspensions. In the pressured environment of adjustment, the response of donors and recipient governments is often to devise makeshift interim modifications, and accept pro forma compliance with targets and conditions in order to keep tranche disbursements on track.11

Regarding the interaction among leaders, the bureaucracy and external actors, increasing access to policy debates raises the possibility of more numerous and potentially conflicting demands being placed on decision-makers and administrative systems, and increases the risk of alienating supporters. For example, increasing information flows and transparency can reveal the points of corruption where gov- ernment resources are diverted through patronage to supporters and/or used to ex- tract rents, thus calling into question the legitimacy and probity of the regime (van de Walle 1994; World Bank 1994b). In many African countries, however, ruling elites and govemments have to some extent been overtaken by events; liberalization has pushed them to be more responsive in order to maintain stability and survive (Bratton and van de Walle 1992; Young 1994).

As a function of these changes, issues arise about the capacity of civil society to participate in the policy process. These deal with the demand side of participation in policy, as a complement to the supply side relating to government institutional commitment and capacity to cope with participation by external actors (Landell-Mills 1992; Mbembe 1993). Much attention in the literature focuses on the capacity of NGOs to aggregate interests effectively and communicate to members, politicians and policy-makers (Bratton 1989b, 1990; Chazan 1982; Fowler 1991; Shaw 1990). For example, NGOs can help rural residents channel their views into national policy

136 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

debates if the NGOs have sufficient technical expertise in the policy area, basic managerial skills, a willing constituency, and a recognized track record (VanSant 1989). The institutional strengths and weaknesses of the media are also critical given the centrality of information flows to a participatory policy process (West and Fair 1993; Zaffiro 1993). ~2

A debate within the civil society literature exists regarding the extent to which the groups classed as members of civil society are themselves, or should be, democratic and participatory in nature. Civil society is often promoted as a sort of "incubator" for democracy (Diamond 1994).13 Yet Bratton points out that "associational life" in Africa should not automatically be assumed to be democratic; rather, this assump- tion needs to be posed as a topic for investigation: "Is there internal democracy in the organizations of civil society? Or do these structures mirror and reinforce the personalistic and authoritarian patterns of rule that prevail at the political center?" (1989a, 430). Monga (1995), for example, echoing Bratton's questions, notes the tendency in Africa for groups in civil society to be exclusionary, and cautions against excessive expectations for civil society leading the way to better governance arrangements. A dilemma for participatory governance is how to structure state- society relations so that one set of clientelist relations is not simply replaced with a new one, where the clients are the most powerful civil society groups rather than the old elites (Rothchild 1994; Rothchild and Foley 1988). Government responsiveness to demands for participation in the policy process can foster democracy to the extent that state-society relations allow space for multiple groups to compete for access to decision-makers. In weak African states, however, creating and maintaining this space can be problematic (Migdal 1988; Harbeson et al. 1994; Hyden and Bratton 1992).

Key Findings and Condusions

This final section summarizes the major findings and conclusions synthesized from the literature reviewed. The discussion addresses both the analytic and opera- tional issues presented in the introduction as of key concern to international donors and African governments. The section concludes with a note of caution about over- estimating the degree to which increased participation can contribute to better policy reform in Africa.

Participation and Successful Policy Reform

Regarding the questions this article explores, the general findings are, first, that the pattern of participation is an important variable in the policy reform process, but that its effects on reform outcomes are strongly mediated by African political and governance factors. Second, increased participation appears to enhance prospects for sustainable policy reform outcomes, though the relative absence of institutional- ized mediating structures and processes makes increasing participation highly vul- nerable to the discretion of political authorities. Given the limited capacity and

Brinkerhoff and Kulibaba 137

r e s p o n s i v e n e s s o f the s ta te and the i n c i p i e n t na tu r e o f c i v i l s o c i e t y ' s a s s o c i a t i o n a l

i n f r a s t ruc tu r e in m u c h o f Af r i c a , c r e a t i n g o p p o r t u n i t i e s fo r p a r t i c i p a t i o n a n d in s t i t u -

t i o n a l i z i n g the p r o c e s s o v e r t i m e are e x a c t i n g t a sks fo r r e f o r m e r s . T h e f o l l o w i n g

spec i f i c c o n c l u s i o n s e m e r g e :

�9 No single regime type is optimal for reform success. However, democratizing regimes offer more numerous and varied opportunities for participation than authoritarian ones. Since eco- nomic reform consolidation requires a broadbased supportive coalition, the ability of democra- tizing regimes to forge and maintain interest group support gives them an implementation advantage in the later phases of the economic policy reform sequence. The policy space such regimes create offers suitable fora for debate, negotiation, and consensus-building among af- fected stakeholders, both inside and outside government.

�9 Reform is not a mechanistic process and cannot be implemented by fiat. Reform is interactive, requiring negotiation, modification of views, compromise, concessions, and management of risks. Even stroke-of-the-pen reforms require public education and political marketing. The key to success is the ability of government and stakeholders to forge consensus, deal with opposi- tion, and develop reform strategies and sequencing that soften negative impacts for the most vulnerable while increasing the chances for intended long-term benefits.

�9 A society rich in social capital and associational life provides numerous channels for interest articulation and participation. However, broader participation in the policy arena becomes more likely when affected groups can translate their economic interests into political pressures. In the African context, this translation process remains constrained by ethnic and cultural particular- ism, although in some countries the growth of an urban middle class offers the possibility of broader-based economic policy coalitions.

�9 More participation in policy reform leads to better technical content in policies. Involvement of well-trained technocrats and informed stakeholders provides a stronger basis for designing and sequencing reforms and grounds reform prescriptions in local realities.

�9 More participation leads to greater sustainability because more affected interests can be in- cluded and satisfied, but also to greater uncertainty and conflict, particularly where losers are relatively powerful and well organized. Governments are more willing to pursue reforms when their concerns about the political risks are addressed, and donors need to find ways of helping governments to overcome these concems.

�9 More participation is harder to manage and requires a flexible, strategic approach. This calls for new management skills and a supportive institutional framework.

Techniques for Promoting Participation in Policy Reform

To s u p p o r t i n c r e a s e d p a r t i c i p a t i o n in the r e f o r m p r o c e s s , n e w a n a l y t i c a p p r o a c h e s

and tools a re c a l l e d for. T h e resu l t s o f ou r s tudy s u g g e s t the f o l l o w i n g o p e r a t i o n a l

c o n c l u s i o n s :

�9 Better political and institutional analysis can help to anticipate policy blockages and problem areas. Analysis should be an ongoing part of implementation as well as input to policy design, and African policy managers need to be central participants in these analytic exercises.

�9 A collaborative design process that integrates implementation considerations into policy content builds participation and increases sustainability. Collaborative design fosters consensus and increases technical efficiency.

�9 The technical content of reforms can be redesigned to increase opportunities for participation; for example, decentralization, matching grants, revenue-sharing mechanisms, development foun- dations; or design of the M&E component, where research centers and/or local NGOs can be built in as participants in data collection on policy impacts.

�9 Institutional capacity-building is needed as a complement to reform. Policy champions are important but cannot singlehandedly overcome ingrained institutional weaknesses and the power of vested interests. Targets of capacity-building are not just public agencies, but include NGOs

138 Studies in Comparative International Development I Fall 1996

and civil society, private sector groups, political parties, and the media. Reform is uncertain and so is participation. Contingency planning is needed with more flexibil- ity, openness to "mid-course" corrections in implementation, and less reliance upon pre-identifying targets and fixed disbursement triggers.

The Limits of Participation

The existing literature provides a rich base of experience and lessons for address- ing the issue of increased participation in policy reform, as evidenced by this re- view. Nevertheless, because participation has once again become "fashionable," we need to be aware of the pitfalls of expecting too much from efforts to promote increased participation. The sociopolitical and economic dynamics in today's Africa create significant uncertainties and obstacles. One astute Africa scholar, Thomas Callaghy, sounds an apprgpriately cautionary note, saying that, "Africa will not b e . . . a neighborhood where either Western-style liberal democracy or African 'imag- ined republics' with mass participation and development are very common" (1994, 144). However, participatory policy prescriptions currently advocated for Africa from both international donor and African sources appear to subscribe, at least implicitly, to these scenarios. Several of the bilateral donor agencies and the inter- national NGO community, for example, are strongly advocating democratization and increased reliance on civil society. Yet, political liberalization, in and of itself, will not lead to increased state effectiveness and responsiveness, or to the reduction of corruption and of the influence of entrenched, self-interested authorities; nor will it automatically ensure the harmonious, broad interplay of competitive societal in- terests. Similarly, increasing civil society's capacity to cooperate with, and make demands on, the state will not, in and of itself, lead to better governance and more development in the absence of a functioning institutional framework for such inter- action (Rothchild 1994). In far too many African countries, the existing framework is under a high degree of stress and/or showing signs of disintegration. In extreme cases, the state has collapsed, with authority structures imploded, and basic govern- ment operations in disarray (Zartman 1994).

The above caveat notwithstanding, the "Afro-pessimism" that characterizes much of the debate about the future of economic and political reform on the continent is overstated. Not all the news is bad. In some countries--for example, Ghana, Mali, Senegal, South Africa and Zambia--economic and political reforms have begun to bear fruit, which has led to renewed hope that Africa's decline can be reversed. Nonetheless, it is important to be aware of participation's limits as well as its potential contributions to economic policy reform in the context of political liberal- ization, and to recognize the long-term nature of the transition to new modes of state-society cooperation.

Notes

This article is a revised and shortened version of a study conducted by the authors for the U.S. Agency for International Development's Bureau for Africa, funded through USAID's Implementing Policy Change

Brink~rlaoff and Kulibaba 139

Project, in support of the multi-donor Working Group on Economic Policy Reform in the Context of Political Liberalization, Special Program for Africa (SPA). Earlier versions were presented at a USAID seminar in Washington for the Agency's Africa Bureau senior staff, at a meeting of the SPA Working Group hosted by the Commission of the European Community, Directorate General for Development, in Brussels, and subsequently at a staff seminar at the European Centre for Development Policy Manage- ment in Maastricht. The views expressed are solely those of the authors and should not be attributed to USAID or the members of the SPA.

1. Three informative compilations that illustrate the current state of the debate are the October 1994 special issue of the Journal of Democracy, Vol. 5; the chapters in Haggard and Webb (1994) and those in Widner (1994).

2. The head of the U.S. Agency for International Development affirmed the centrality of participation in USAID policy and procedures and established a working group on participation (Atwood 1993). Simi- larly, the World Bank set up a learning group on participation that has commissioned numerous analyses of participation, held several conferences to discuss findings and their policy implications, and issued a summary report, which concludes with recommendations on "mainstreaming" participation in Bank activities (see World Bank 1994c). Interest in participation is far from new. In the late 1960s donor agencies were urging developing country governments to encourage popular participation as a means to further development impacts and to reduce political instability (see, for example, Hapgood 1969).

3. Interest in civil society has mushroomed dramatically among both scholars and practitioners. In the wake of the global trend toward democratization, the power and potential of popular mobilization to drastically reconfigure sociopolitical landscapes hold a strong allure. Studies such as Putnam's (1993) have focused international donors' attentions on the catalytic properties of civic associations for economic develop- ment. Regarding Africa, there is ongoing debate over the features and potential of civil society in the African context, and how the conceptualization is applicable (see for example Bratton 1989a; Harbeson et al. 1994; Jeffries 1993; Lemarchand 1992; Monga 1995; Woods 1992). For an informative overview of the literature, see Coston (1995).

4. See the discussion of the governance concept, with a focus on the links to economic reform, in Frischtak (1994); for an extensive review of these issues in Africa, see Healey and Robinson (1992). See also Hyden's seminal study (1983), as well as his later work (1992). The World Bank's approach to framing governance issues has been widely accepted by other international donor agencies.

5. This article limits its inquiry to participation in the economic policy reform process in Africa. This choice ruled out the vast literature on political and electoral participation, except as it relates to economic development. However, several important early sources deserve mention for laying some of the concep- tual and analytic groundwork upon which later studies have built. These include, among others, Hirschman's (1969) classic on citizen responses to government policies (exit, voice, loyalty), Pateman's (1970) study of the relationships between participation and democracy, and Huntington and Nelson's (1976) work on how governments can manage citizen participation. In addition, this study did not delve in-depth into the huge literature on project participation and community development. For overviews see Cohen and Uphoff (1980), Finsterbusch and Van Wicklin (1987), and Nagle (1991). Further, the study takes an instrumental focus on participation, concentrating on literature that discusses what participation contributes, or doesn't, to the economic reform process. Thus, the review deemphasizes the literature whose major orientation to participation is in terms of human rights, cultural authenticity, moral impera- tives, and so on.

6. The requirements of stabilization and adjustment policies call for more, not less, government, leading to what Callaghy (1990) terms the "orthodox paradox." For discussion of the need for improved govern- ment capacity in post-apartheid South Africa, see the chapters in Fitzgerald et al. (1995).

7. The World Bank links participation via voice and exit to governance in that opportunities to either articulate preferences and express them to decision-makers or to choose alternative service delivery arrangements (exit) can increase accountability at multiple levels (1992: 22-28).

8. For some, NGOs are key to redefining development in terms of community empowerment, local control, and sustainability (see for example, Korten 1990).

9. A vast body of literature discusses the nature of the state in sub-Saharan Africa, most of it in the political economy stream cited earlier. Chazan et al. (1992) define the state as "a set of associations and agencies" that exercises control over defined territories and their populations through decision-making structures (executives, parties, parliaments), decision-enforcing institutions (bureaucracies, parastatal organizations, and security forces) and decision-mediating bodies (primarily courts, tribunals, and investigatory com- missions). This perspective is useful in that it places emphasis on the organic functioning of institutions.

140 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

See also Harbeson et al. (1994) and Widner (1994). 10. The World Bank's approach to governance is an interesting example of treating a fundamentally political

arena in largely technical terms (1992, 1994b). To see how the Bank has sought to operationalize the approach for civil service reform, consult Pinto (1994).

1 I. See, for example, the country case studies in Widner (1994). In a similar vein, see Berg's (1990) and Ka and van de Walle's (1994) analyses of Senegal's adjustment experience. See also Rondinelli and Mont- gomery (1990).

12. As Zaffiro observes, "to study the press and broadcasting [in contemporary Africa] is to unavoidably and deeply enter the realm of political and social policy analysis" (1993, 7). West and Fair echo this perspective: "political decisions made by African governments have precluded decentralization or de- mocratization of mass media forms such as newspaper or radio" (1993, 98).

13. See also Diamond's earlier work on democracy in Africa (Diamond et al. 1988). For further discussion and additional sources on this topic, see the literature review in Coston (1995).

References

ABBOT[', G.C. 1993 Debt relief and sustainable development in sub-Saharan Africa. Aldershot, England:

Edward Elgar Publishing. ADAMOLEKUN, L.

1988 Political leadership in sub-Saharan Africa: From giants to dwarfs. International Political Science Review 9, 2: 95-106.

AKE, C. 1990 Sustaining development on the indigenous. In The long-term perspective study of

sub-Saharan Africa. volume 3. Institutional and sociopolitical issues; 7-22. Washington, DC: World Bank.

AMI~THIER, J. 1989 Mobilisation de l'epargne en milieu rural: l'exemple ivoirien. Abidjan: Editions CEDA.

ATHERTON, J.S., DEVINE, D., GRIMM, C., HARMSWORTH, J. AND NELSON, P. 1992 Local participation in the design and implementation of DFA programs: Some lessons

from the field. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Bureau for Africa, November.

ATWOOD, J.B. 1993 Statement of principles on participatory development. Washington, DC: Address pre-

sented at Academy for Educational Development, USAID Forum on Participatory Devel- opment, November 16.

AYITI'EY, G.B.N. 1990 Indigenous African systems: An assessment. In The long-term perspective study of

sub-Saharan Africa. volume 3. Institutional and sociopolitical issues, World Bank, 22- 32. Washington, D.C.

1991 Indigenous African institutions. New York: Transnational Press. BALOGUN, M.J. AND MUTAHABA, G., EDS.

1989 Economic restructuring and African public administration: Issues, actions, and future choices. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press

BATES, R.H. 1981 Markets and states in tropical Africa: The political basis of agricultural policies. Berke-

ley: University of California Press. 1988 The political basis for agricultural policy reform. In Africa's development challenges and

the World Bank: Hard questions, costly choices, edited by S.K. Commins, 115-32. Boul- der, CO: Lynn Rienner Publishers.

BATES, R.H. AND COLLIER, P. 1992 The politics and economics of policy reform in Zambia. Oxford, England: Centre for the

Study of African Economies, February. BATES, R.H. AND KRUEGER, A.O., EDS.

1993 Political and economic interactions in economic policy reform: Evidence from eight countries. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Brinkerhoffand Kullbaba 141

BECKMAN, B. 1992 Empowerment or repression? The World Bank and the politics of African adjustment. In

Authoritarianism, democracy and adjustment: The politics of economic reform in Africa, edited by P. Gibbon, Y. Pangura, and A. Ofstad, 83-105. Uppsata, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.

Adjustment postponed: Economic policy reform in Senegal in the 1980s. Alexandria, VA: Elliot Berg Associates. Report prepared for U.S. Agency for International Develop- ment/Dakar. October.

1991 African adjustment programs: False attacks and true dilemmas. Washington, DC: The American University, Department of Economics. Paper presented at the Conference on Structural Adjustment: Retrospect and Prospect. March.

BHATNAGAR, B. AND WILLIAMS, A.C., EDS. 1992 Participatory development and the World Bank: Potential directions for change. Wash-

ington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 183. BIENEN, H.

1990 The politics of trade liberalization in Africa. Economic Development and Cultural Change 38: 713-32.

1993 Leaders, violence, and the absence of change in Africa. Political Science Quarterly 108: 271-83.

BIENEN, H. AND WATERBURY, J. 1989 The political economy of privatization in developing countries. World Development 17,

5: 617-32. BIERMANN, W.

1988 Tanzanian politics under IMF pressure. In Tanzania after Nyerere, edited by M. Hodd, 175-83. New York: Pinter Publishers.

BOYLE, A.K. 1993 State and society in sub-Saharan Africa (primarily in the Sahel countries): Aid agencies,

civil society and the operating logic of the State. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Club du Sahel. Discussion Paper for the Donors' Advi- sory Group Meeting, Berlin, April.

BRATTON, M. 1989a Beyond the state: Civil society and associational life in Africa. World Politics 41, 3: 440-

30. 1989b The politics of government-NGO relations in Africa. World Development 17, 5: 569-89. 1990 Non-governmental organizations in Africa: Can they influence public policy? Develop-

ment and Change 21 : 87-I 18. BRATTON, M. AND VAN DE WALLE, N.

1992 Toward governance in Africa: Popular demands and state responses. In Governance and politics in Africa, edited by Hyden, G. and Bratton, M., 27-57. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

BRINKERHOFF, D.W. 1991 Improving development program performance: Guidelines for managers. Boulder, CO:

Lynne Rienner Publishers. 1995 African state-society linkages in transition: The case of forestry policy in Mali. Canadian

Journal of Development Studies 16, 2: 201-228. BRINKERHOFF, D.W. AND MORGAN, E.P.

1989 The dance of structural adjustment: Policy reform as partisan mutual adaptation. Miami, FL: American Society for Public Administration. Paper presented at the 50th National Conference. April 9-13.

BROWN, DL 1989 Bureaucracy as an issue in third world management: An African case study. Public

Administration and Development 9, 4: 369-80. CALLAGHY, T.M.

1989 Toward state capability and embedded liberalism in the third world: Lessons for adjust- ment. In Fragile coalitions: The politics of economic adjustment, edited by J.M. Nelson, et al., 115-34. Washington, DC: Overseas Development Council.

BERG, E. 1990

142 Studies in Comparative International Development I Fall 1996

1990 Lost between state and market: The politics of economic adjustment in Ghana, Zambia, and Nigeria. In Economic crisis and policy choice: The politics of adjustment in the third world, edited by J.M. Nelson, 257-321, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

1994 Africa: Back to the future? Journal of Democracy 5, 4:133--46. CAMPBELL, H.

1992 The politics of demobilization in Tanzania: Beyond nationalism. In Tanzania and the IMF: The dynamics of liberalization, edited by H. Campbell, and H. Stein, Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

CSIS (CENTER FOR STRATEGIC AND INTERNATIONAL STUDIES) 1992 The politics of economic reform in sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: Author. Final

report prepared for U.S. Agency for International Development. CHARLICK, R.

1992 The concept of governance and its implications for A.I.D.'s development assistance program in Africa. Washington, DC: Associates in Rural Development, Inc. Paper pre- pared for U.S. Agency for International Development, Africa Bureau Democracy and Governance Program. June.

CHAZAN, N. 1982 The new politics of participation in tropical Africa. Comparative Politics 14,2: 169-89. 1983 An anatomy of Ghanaian politics: Managing political recession, 1969-1982. Boulder,

CO: Westview Press. 1992a Liberalization, governance, and political space in Ghana. In Governance and Politics in

Africa, edited by G. Hyden and M. Bratton, 121--43. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Pub- lishers.

1992b The dynamics of civil society in Africa. Jerusalem: Hebrew University. Paper presented at the International Conference on Civil Society, January.

CHAZAN, N., MORTIMER, R., RAVENHILL, J. AND ROTHCHILD, D. 1992 Politics and society in contemporary Africa, 2d ed. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publish-

ers. CHOLE, E.

1989

CLARK, J. 1991

The African economic crisis: Origins and impact on society. In Economic Restructuring and African Public Administration: Issues, Actions, and Future Choices, edited by J.M. Balogun and G. Mutahaba, 3-29. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press.

Democratizing development: The role of voluntary organizations. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press.

COHEN, J.M., GRINDLE, M.S., AND WALKER, S.T 1985 Foreign aid and conditions precedent: Political and bureaucratic dimensions. World De-

velopment 13, 12: 1211-30. COHEN, J.M. AND UPHOFF, N.T.

1980 Participation's place in rural development: Seeking clarity through specificity. World Development 8, 3: 213-35.

COLBOURN, F.D. 1989 Everyday forms ofpeasant resistance. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe, Inc.

COMMONWEALTH SECRETARIAT AND AFRICAN ASSOCIATION FOR PUBLIC ADMINIS- TRATION AND MANAGEMENT

1990 Enhancement of public policy management capacity in Africa. London and Addis Ababa: Authors, Report of the High-Level Working Group Meeting, Mahe, Seychelles, 24--27 September.

CORBO V. AND FISCHER, S. 1990 Adjustment programs and bank support: Rationale and main results. Washington, DC:

World Bank. Paper presented at Conference on Policies for the Recovery of Growth: Adjustment Lending Revisited, September 13-14.

COSTON, J.M. 1995 Civil society literature review: Democratic governance and civil society's theoretical

development, contemporary, conceptualization, and institutional, economic, and political implications. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Global Bu- reau, Center for Democracy and Governance, March.

Bdnkerhoffand Kdibaba 143

CROSBY, B.L. 1992a Management and the environment for implementation of political change: Part one, po-

litical mapping. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Imple- menting Policy Change Project, Technical Note No. 4.

1992b Stakeholder analysis: A vital tool for strategic managers. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Implementing Policy Change Project, Technical Note No. 2.

CROOK, R. 1990 Politics, the cocoa crisis, and administration in Cote d'Ivoire. Journal of Modern African

Studies 28, 4: 649-66. DIAMOND, L.

1994 Rethinking civil society: Toward democratic consolidation. Journal of Democracy 5, 3: 4-17.

DIAMOND, L., LINZ, J.J., AND LIPSET, S.M., EDS. 1988 Democracy in developing countries: Africa, vol. II. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publish-

ers. EDWARDS, M. AND HULME, D., EDS.

1992 Making a difference: NGOs and development in a changing worM. London: Earthscan Publications.

ELA, J.M. 1992 Quand l'dtat p~n~tre en brousse, les ripostes paysannes h la crise. Paris: Editions Karthala.

ETOUNGA-MANGUELLE, D. 1991 L'Afrique a-t-elle besoin d'un programme d'ajustement culturel? lvry-sur-Seine: Edi-

tions Nouvelles du Sud. EVANS, P.

1992

FEARON, J. 1988

The state as problem and solution: Predation, embedded autonomy, and structural change. In The politics of economic adjustment, edited by S. Haggard and R.R. Kaufman, 139-82. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

International financial institutions and economic policy reform in sub-Saharan Africa. The Journal of Modern African Studies 26, I: I 13-137.

FINSTERBUSCH, K. AND VAN W1CKLIN 111, W.A. 1987 The contribution of beneficiary participation to development project effectiveness. Public

Administration and Development 7, 1 : 1-23. FITZGERALD, P., MCLENNAN, A., AND MUNSLOW, B., EDS.

1995 Managing sustainable development in South Africa. Oxford and Cape Town: Oxford University Press.

FOWLER, A. 1991 The role of NGOs in changing state-society relations: Perspectives from eastern and

southern Africa. Development Policy Review 9: 53-84. FRISCHTAK, L.L

1994 Governance capacity and economic reform in developing countries. Washington, DC: World Bank, Technical Paper No. 254.

GARVEY, B. 1991 Patrimonial economics and formal bureaucracies: Public administration and social reality

in the least developed countries of the 1990's: A review article. Public Administration and Development 11, 6: 591-600.

GLADWIN, C.H., ED. 1991 Structural adjustment and African women farmers. Gainesville: University of Florida

Press. GOLDSMITH, A.A.

1993 Demand, supply and institutional development in Africa. Canadian Journal of Develop- ment Studies 14, 3: 413--429.

GOOD, K. 1989 Debt and the one-party state in Zambia. Journal of Modern African Studies 27, 2: 297-

313.

144 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

GORDON, D.F. 1991 Beyond policy reform in Africa: Sustaining development through strengthening entrepre-

neurship and the non-governmental sector. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for Interna- tional Development. Implementing Policy Change Project, Working Paper No. 2, No- vember.

GREENAWAY, D. AND MORISSEY, O. 1993 Structural adjustment and liberalisation in developing countries: What lessons have we

learned. Kyklos 46: 241--61. GRINDLE, M.

1991 The new political economy: Positive economics and negative politics. In Politics and Policy Making in Developing Countries: Perspectives on the New Political Economy, edited by G.M. Meier, 41--62. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.

GRINDLE, M. AND THOMAS, J. 1990 After the decision: Implementing policy reforms in developing countries. World Develop-

ment 18, 8:1163-81. 1991 Public choices and policy change: The political reform in developing countries. Balti-

more, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. GULHATI, R.

1988 The political economy of reform in sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank, EDI Policy Seminar Report No. 8.

1989 Impasse in Zambia: The economics and politics of reform. Washington, DC: World Bank, Economic Development Institute.

1990a The making of economic policy in Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank, Economic Development Institute.

1990b Who makes economic policy in Africa and how? World Development 18, 8:1147-61. HAGGARD, S. AND KAUFMAN, R.R.

1994 The challenges of consolidation. Journal of Democracy 5, 6: 5-17. HAGGARD, S. AND KAUFMAN, R.R., EDS.

1992 The politics of economic adjustment. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. HAGGARD, S. AND WEBB, S.B., EDS.

1994 Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment. New York: Oxford University Press.

HAPGOOD, D., ED. 1969 The role of popular participation in development: Report of a conference on the imple-

mentation of Title IX of the Foreign Assistance Act. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press.

HARBESON, J.W., ROTHCHILD, D., AND CHAZAN, N., EDS. 1994 Civil society and the state in Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

HARRIGAN, J. 1991 Malawi. Aid and power: The World Bank and policy-based lending, edited by Mosley, P.

Harrigan, J. and Toye, J. London: Routledge, Vol. 2: Case Studies, 201-67. HAWKINS JR., J.J.

1991 Understanding the failure of IMF reform: The Zambian case. World Development 19, 7: 839--49.

HEALEY, J. AND ROBINSON, M. 1992 Democracy, governance and economic policy. Sub-Saharan Africa in comparative per-

spective. London: Overseas Development Institute. HEILBRUNN, J.R.

1993 Social origins of national conferences in Benin and Togo. Journal of Modem African Studies 31 : 277-99.

HERBST, J. 1993 The politics of reform in Ghana, 1982-1991. Berkeley: University of California Press.

HERMAN, C. 1986 Information planning for policy reform programs. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for

International Development, Evaluation Occasional Paper No. 13, August. HIRSCHMAN, A.O,

1969 Exit, voice, and loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Brinkerhoff and Kulibaba 145

HUSAIN, I. 1994

HYDEN, G. 1983

HIRSCHMANN, D. 1993 Institutional development in the era of economic policy reform: Concerns, contradictions,

and illustrations from Malawi. Public Administration and Development 13, 2:113-28. HUNTINGTON, S.P. AND NELSON, J.M.

1976 No easy choice: Political participation in developing countries. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

AND FARUQEE, R., EDS. Adjustment in Africa: Lessons from country case studies. Washington, DC: World Bank.

1990

1992

HYDEN, G. 1992

ISRAEL, A. 1987

No shortcuts to progress: African development management in comparative perspective. Berkeley: University of California Press. Creating an enabling environment. In World Bank, The long-term perspective study of sub-Saharan Africa. volume 3. Institutional and sociopolitical issues. Washington, DC: Author, 73-81. Governance and the study of politics. In Governance and Politics in Africa, edited by G. Hyden and M. Bratton, 1-27. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. AND BRATI'ON, M., EDS. Governance and politics in Africa. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

1993

JOHNSON, 1993

JOLLY, R. 1988

Institutional development: Incentives to performance. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

JEFFRIES, R. 1991 Leadership commitment and political opposition to structural, adjustment in Ghana. In

Ghana: The political economy of recovery, edited by D. Rothchild, 157-72. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. The state, structural adjustment and good government in Africa. Journal of Common- wealth and Comparative Politics 31, 1 : 20-35.

J.H. AND WASTY, S.S. Borrower ownership of adjustment programs and the political economy of reform. Wash- ington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 199.

Poverty and adjustment in the 1990s. In Strengthening the poor." What have we learned? edited by J.P. Lewis, et al., 163-74. Washington, DC: Overseas Development Council.

KA, S. AND VAN DE WALLE, N. 1994 Senegal: Stalled reform in a dominant party system. In Voting for reform: Democracy,

political liberalization, and economic adjustment, edited by S. Haggard and S.B. Webb, 290-360. New York: Oxford University Press.

KIGGUNDU, M.N. 1989 Managing organizations in developing countries: An operational and strategic approach.

West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press. KIONDO, A.S.Z.

1989 The politics of economic reforms in Tanzania: 1977-1988. University of Toronto, Un- published Ph.D. Dissertation.

KOM, A. 1993 Intellectuels africains et enjeux de la d6mocratie: mis~re, r6pression et exil. Politique

Africaine 51: 61-9. KORTEN, D.C.

1990 Getting to the 21st century: Voluntary action and the global agenda. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press.

KRUEGER, A.O. 1993 Political economy of policy reform in developing countries. Cambridge, MA: Massachu-

setts Institute of Technology Press. KULIBABA, N.

1993a Improving the effectiveness of policy reform in Africa: Cocoa marketing reform in Ghana. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Agricultural Policy Analysis Project, Phase II.

146 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

1993b Improving the effectiveness of policy reform in Africa: Marketing reforms in Malawi. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Agricultural Policy Analysis Project, Phase II.

KULIBABA, N. AND RIELLY, C. 1993 Improving the effectiveness of policy reform in Africa: A synthesis of lessons learned.

Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Agricultural Policy Analysis Project, Phase II.

KYDD, J. 1989

LAMB, G. 1987

Zambia in the 1980s: The political economy of adjustment. In Structural adjustment and agriculture-theory and practice in Africa and Latin America. edited by S. Commander, 127-44. London: Overseas Development Institute.

Managing economic policy change: Institutional dimensions. Washington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 14.

LANDELL-MILLS, P. 1992 Governance, cultural change, and empowerment. Journal of Modern African Studies 30,

4: 543-67.

Women and structural transformation. Economic Development and Cultural Change 34, 2: 195-221.

1990 Structural adjustment, agricultural development and the poor: Some lessons from the Malawian experience. World Development 18, 9:1207-19.

LEMARCHAND, R. 1992 Uncivil states and civil societies: How illusion became reality. Journal of Modern Afri-

can Studies 30, 2: 177-91. LEONARD, D.K,

1991 African successes: Four public managers of Kenyan rural development. Berkeley: Uni- versity of California Press.

LIDDLE, R.W. 1992 The politics of development policy. Worm Development 20, 6: 793-807.

LIEBERSON, J.M. 1991 A.I.D. economic policy reform programs in Africa: A synthesis of findings from six

evaluations, Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Program and Operations Assessment Report No. 1, December.

LINDENBERG, M. AND DEVARAJAN, S. 1993 Prescribing strong economic medicine: Revisiting myths about structural adjustment,

democracy, and performance in developing countries. Comparative Politics 25, 2: 169- 82.

MACGAFFEY, J,, MUKOHYA, V., WA NKERA, R., SCHOEPF, B.G., MAVAMBU YE BEDA, M. AND ENGUNDU, W.

1991 The real economy of Zaire: The contribution of smuggling and other unofficial activities to national wealth. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

MBEMBE, A. 1993 D6flation de l'6tat, civilit6 et citoyennet6 en Afrique noire. Philadelphia: University of

Pennsylvania, unpublished paper. MCCLEARY, W.A.

1991 The design and implementation of conditionality. In Restructuring economies in distress: Policy reform and the World Bank, edited by V. Thomas, A. Chhibber, A. Dailami, J. de Melo, 197-215. New York: Oxford University Press.

MIGDAL, J.S. 1988 Strong societies and weak states: State-society relations and state capabilities in the third

world. Princeton: Princeton University Press. MIKELL, G.

1989 Peasant politicisation and economic recuperation in Ghana: Local and national dilemmas. Journal of Modern African Studies 27, 3: 455-78.

MILLS, C.A. 1989 Structural adjustment in sub-Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank, EDI Policy

Seminar Report No. 18.

LELE, U. 1986

Brinkerhoff and Kulibaba 147

MOLUTSI, P.P. AND HOLM, J.D. 1992 State-society relations in Botswana: Beginning liberalization. In Governance and Politics

in Africa, edited by G. Hyden and M. Bratton, 75-95. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

MONGA, C. 1994a Anthropologie de la colbre. Socigtd et ddmocratie en Afrique. Paris: L'Harmattan. 1994b Social responses to trade liberalization in Cameroon. Time inconsistency and compatibil-

ity issues in the Franc Zone. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government, unpublished seminar paper, January.

1995 Civil society and democratisation in francophone Africa, Journal of Modern African Studies 33, 3.

MONTGOMERY, J.D. 1988 Bureaucrats and people: Grassroots participation in third world development. Baltimore:

Johns Hopkins University Press. MOSLEY, P., HARRIGAN, J. AND TOYE, J.

1991 Aid and power: The WorldBank and policy-based lending. New York: Routledge, Vol. 1. MUTAHABA, G., BAGUMA, R. AND HALFANI, M.

1993 Vitalizing African public administration for recovery and development. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press.

MUTAHABA, G. AND BALOGUN, M.J., EDS. 1992 Enhancing policy management capacity in Africa. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press.

NAGLE, W.J. 1991 Policy and practice of community participation in the U.S. Agency for International

Development. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Office of Education, Social Sector Policy Analysis Project, November.

NELSON, J.M., ED. 1990 Economic crisis andpolicy choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

NELSON, J.M. 1989 Overview: The politics of long-haul economic reform. In Fragile coalitions: The politics

of economic adjustment, edited by J.M. Nelson, et al., 3-27. Washington, DC: Overseas Development Council.

NUNBERG, B. 1990 Public sector management issues in structural adjustment lending. Washington, DC:

World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 99. NYANG'ORO, J.E. AND SHAW, T.M., EDS.

1992 Beyond structural adjustment in Africa. The political economy of sustainable and demo- cratic development. New York: Praeger.

OBASANJO, O. AND D'ORVILLE, H., EDS. 1991 The leadership challenge of economic reforms in Africa. New York: Crane Russak.

OUANE, H. 1990 La p6restroika et l'6conomie africaine. Afrique 2000 1: 33--46..

OYUGI, W.O. 1994 Kenya: Contextual factors and the policy process. In Policy reform for sustainability in

Africa, edited by M. Garritty and L. Picard, 81-99. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publish- ers.

PATEMAN, C. 1970 Participation and democratic theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

PAUL, S. 1990 Institutional reforms in sector adjustment operations: The World Bank's experience.

Washington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 92. PE, AN, P.

1993 Affaires africains. Paris: Fayard. PICARD, L.A.

1987 The politics of development in Botswana: A model for success? Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

148 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

PICARD, L.A. AND GARRITY, M., EDS. 1994 Policy reform for sustainable development in Africa: The institutional imperative. Boul-

der, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. PINTO, R., WITH MROPE, A.J.

1994 Projectizing the governance approach to civil service reform: An institutional environ- ment assessment for preparing a sectoral adjustment loan in the Gambia. Washington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 252.

PRYOR, F. 1990 Malawi and Madagascar: The political economy of poverty, equity and growth. Oxford,

UK: Oxford University Press, World Bank Comparative Study. PUTNAM, R., WITH LEONARDI, R. AND NANE'ITI, R.Y.

1993 Making democracy work: Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton Univer- sity Press.

RIELLY, C 1993 Improving the effectiveness of policy reform in Africa: Rice market liberalization in

Madagascar. Washington, DC: U.S. Agency for International Development, Agricultural Policy Analysis Project, Phase II.

ROBINSON, B. 1990 Collaborative sector analysis: A foreign assistance technique for improving LDC sector

management. World Development 18, 7:1015-29. RONDINELLI, D.A. AND MONTGOMERY, J.D.

1990 Managing economic reform in Africa: An alternative perspective on structural adjustment policies. Policy Sciences 23 1 : 73-93.

ROTHCHILD, D. 1994 Structuring state-society relations in Africa: Toward an enabling political environment. In

Economic change and political liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa, edited by J.A. Widner, 201-229. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

ROTHCHILD, D., ED. 1991 Ghana: The political economy of recovery. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.

ROTHCH1LD, D. AND CHAZAN, N., EDS. 1988 The precarious balance: State and society in Africa. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

ROTHCHILD, D. AND FOLEY, M.W. 1988 African states and the politics of inclusive coalitions. In The precarious balance: State

and society in Africa. edited by D. Rothchild and N. Chazan, 233-265. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

SAHN, D.E. 1990

SAHN, D.E. 1992

SALL, A. 1989

Fiscal and exchange rate reforms in Africa: Considering the impact upon the poor. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, Food and Nutrition Policy Program, Monograph No. 4, August. AND SARRIS. A.H. The political economy of economic decline and reform in Africa: The role of the state, markets and civil institutions. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University, Food and Nutrition Policy Program, Working Paper No. 25, April.

Mali: L' organisation du monde rural du Mall (1910-1988). Bamako: Editions Imprimerie du Mall.

SARRIS, A.H. 1990 A macro-micro framework for analysis of the impact of structural adjustment on the poor

in sub-Saharan Africa. Ithaca, NY: Comell University, Food and Nutrition Policy Pro- gram, Monograph No. 5, September.

SCHOENHOLTZ, A.I. 1987 The I.M.F. in Africa: Unnecessary and undesirable western restraints on development.

Journal of Modern African Studies 25, 3: 403-33. SHAW, T.M.

1990 Popular participation in non-governmental structures in Africa: Implications for demo- cratic development. Africa Today 37, 3: 5-22.

1993 Reformism and revisionism in Africa's political economy in the 1990s: The dialectics of adjustment. New York: St. Martin's Press.

Brinkerhoff and Kulibaba 149

SILVERMAN. J.M. 1996 Analyzing the role of the public sector in Africa: Implications for civil service reform

policy. In Policy Analysis Concepts and Methods: An Institutional and Implementation Focus, edited by D.W. Brinkerhoff. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, Policy Studies and Devel- oping Nations Series (in press).

SIROWY, L. AND INKELES, A. 1990 The effects of democracy on economic growth and inequality: A review. Studies in

Comparative International Development 25, 1 : 126-57. SKALNES, T.

1993 The state interest groups and structural adjustment in Zimbabwe. Journal of Development Studies 29, 3: 401-28.

SMITH, S., COMBEAUD, J. AND MOUTOUT, C. 1990 La guerre du cacao: Histoire secrete d'un embargo. Paris: Calmann-L6vy.

SMITH, S. AND GLASER, A. 1992 Ces messieurs Afrique: Le Paris village du continent noir. Paris: Calmann-L6vy.

SUTTON, F.X. 1987 Building competences for policy analysis and management in developing countries: Asian

and Latin American experience with relevance to Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank, June.

TADESSE, Z. 1992 African debates on social movements and the democratic process. Journal of The Society

for International Development 3: 34-7. TALBOTT, K.

1990 Public participation in African environmental action plans. In World Bank, National Environmental Action Plans in Africa. Proceedings from a workshop organized by the Government of Ireland, the Environmental Institute, University College Dublin, and the World Bank. Dublin, Ireland, December 12-14, pp. 37-47.

TAUBE, G. 1993 Social dimensio~xs of adjustment. Conceptual issues and empirical evidence from Tanza-

nia and other African countries. Afrika Spectrum 28, 2: 165-83. THOMAS, J.W. AND GRINDLE, M.S

1990 After the decision: Implementing policy reforms in developing countries. World Develop- ment 18, 8:1163-81.

THOMAS, V., CHHIBBER, A., DAILAMI, M. AND DE MELO. J., EDS. 1991; Restructuring economies in distress: Policy reform and the World Bank. New York:

Oxford University Press. TOYE, J.

1992 Interest group politics and the implementation of adjustment policies in sub-Saharan Africa. In Authoritarianism, democracy and adjustment: The politics of economic reform in Africa, edited by Gibbon, P., Bangura, Y. and Ofstad, A., 106-126. Uppsala, Sweden: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.

USAID (U.S. AGENCY FOR INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT) n.d. Achieving participation: A collection of the Africa bureau's 'best practices.' Washington,

DC: Author, Bureau for Africa. VAN DE WALLE, N.

1994 Political liberalization and economic policy reform in Africa. World Development 22, 4. VANSANT, J.

1989 Opportunities and risks for private voluntary organizations as agents of LDC policy change. World Development 17, 11: 1723-33.

VONDAL, P. 1989 Operational issues in developing A.I.D. policy reform programs. Washington, DC: U.S.

Agency for International Development, Program Evaluation Discussion Paper No. 28, October.

WATERBURY, J. 1989 The political management of economic adjustment and reform. In Fragile coalitions: The

politics of economic adjustment, edited by J.M Nelson, et al., 39-57. Washington, DC: Overseas Development Council.

150 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

WEDELL, G. 1986 Making broadcasting useful: The African experience. The development of radio and

television in Africa in the 1980's. Manchester, England: Manchester University Press and The European Institute for the Media.

WEST, H.G. AND FAIR, J.E. 1993 Development communication and popular resistance in Africa: An examination of the

struggle over tradition and modernity through media. African Studies Review 36, 1:91- 115.

WHITE, L.G. 1990a Implementing economic policy reforms: Policies and opportunities for donors. World

Development 18, 1: 49---60. 1990b Implementing policy reforms in LDCs: A strategy for designing and effecting change.

Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. 1990c Policy reforms in sub-Saharan Africa: Conditions for establishing a dialogue. Studies in

Comparative International Development 25, 2: 24--42. WIDNER, J.A.

1993 Interest groups and medium-term structural adjustment in C~te d'Ivoire. Abidjan: U.S. Agency for International Development/REDSO.

1994 Economic change and political liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

WIDNER, J.A. AND VAN DER VEEN, M. 1993 Associational life and economic development in Africa: A review of the literature. Cam-

bridge, MA: Harvard University, Center for International Affairs. Paper presented at Workshop on Associational Life and Economic Development in Africa, May 7-8.

WIESNER, D.E. 1993 From macroeconomic correction to public sector reform: The critical role of evaluation.

Washington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 214. WINTER, C.

1984 Structural adjustment lending: Boon or blow for Malawi? Journal of Contemporary Afri- can Studies 4, 1: 103-18.

WISEMAN, J.A. 1990 Democracy in black Africa: Survival and revival New York: Paragon House Publishers.

WOODS, D. 1992 Civil society in Europe and Africa: Limiting state power through a public sphere. African

Studies Review 35, 2: 77-100. WORLD BANK

1989 Sub-Saharan Africa: From crisis to sustainable growth. Washington. DC: Author. 1991 The African capacity building initiative: Toward improved policy analysis and develop-

ment management. Washington, DC: Author. 1992 Governance and development. Washington, DC: Author, April. 1994a Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, results, and the road ahead. New York: Oxford Univer-

sity Press, World Bank Policy Research Report. 1994b Governance: The World Bank's experience. Washington, DC: Author, Development in

Practice Series, May. 1994c The World Bank and participation. Washington, DC: Author, Operations Policy Depart-

ment, September. WUNSCH, J.S. AND OLOWU, D., EDS.

1990 Failure of the centralized state: Institutions and self-governance in Africa. Boulder, CO:

YOUNG, C. 1994

YOUNG, R. 1991

Westview Press.

Democratization in Africa: The contradictions of a political imperative. In Economic change and political liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa, edited by J.A. Widner, 230- 251. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Privatization in Africa. Review of African Political Economy 51 : 50-62.

150 Studies in Comparative International Development / Fall 1996

WEDELL, G. 1986 Making broadcasting useful: The African experience. The development of radio and

television in Africa in the 1980's. Manchester, England: Manchester University Press and The European Institute for the Media.

WEST, H.G. AND FAIR, J.E. 1993 Development communication and popular resistance in Africa: An examination of the

struggle over tradition and modernity through media. African Studies Review 36, 1:91- 115.

WHITE, L.G. 1990a Implementing economic policy reforms: Policies and opportunities for donors. World

Development 18, 1: 49---60. 1990b Implementing policy reforms in LDCs: A strategy for designing and effecting change.

Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. 1990c Policy reforms in sub-Saharan Africa: Conditions for establishing a dialogue. Studies in

Comparative International Development 25, 2: 24--42. WIDNER, J.A.

1993 Interest groups and medium-term structural adjustment in C~te d'Ivoire. Abidjan: U.S. Agency for International Development/REDSO.

1994 Economic change and political liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

WIDNER, J.A. AND VAN DER VEEN, M. 1993 Associational life and economic development in Africa: A review of the literature. Cam-

bridge, MA: Harvard University, Center for International Affairs. Paper presented at Workshop on Associational Life and Economic Development in Africa, May 7-8.

WIESNER, D.E. 1993 From macroeconomic correction to public sector reform: The critical role of evaluation.

Washington, DC: World Bank, Discussion Paper No. 214. WINTER, C.

1984 Structural adjustment lending: Boon or blow for Malawi? Journal of Contemporary Afri- can Studies 4, 1: 103-18.

WISEMAN, J.A. 1990 Democracy in black Africa: Survival and revival New York: Paragon House Publishers.

WOODS, D. 1992 Civil society in Europe and Africa: Limiting state power through a public sphere. African

Studies Review 35, 2: 77-100. WORLD BANK

1989 Sub-Saharan Africa: From crisis to sustainable growth. Washington. DC: Author. 1991 The African capacity building initiative: Toward improved policy analysis and develop-

ment management. Washington, DC: Author. 1992 Governance and development. Washington, DC: Author, April. 1994a Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, results, and the road ahead. New York: Oxford Univer-

sity Press, World Bank Policy Research Report. 1994b Governance: The World Bank's experience. Washington, DC: Author, Development in

Practice Series, May. 1994c The World Bank and participation. Washington, DC: Author, Operations Policy Depart-

ment, September. WUNSCH, J.S. AND OLOWU, D., EDS.

1990 Failure of the centralized state: Institutions and self-governance in Africa. Boulder, CO:

YOUNG, C. 1994

YOUNG, R. 1991

Westview Press.

Democratization in Africa: The contradictions of a political imperative. In Economic change and political liberalization in sub-Saharan Africa, edited by J.A. Widner, 230- 251. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Privatization in Africa. Review of African Political Economy 51 : 50-62.